Changes

Jump to navigation Jump to search
no edit summary
*This page is referenced in [[BPP Field Exam Papers]]
*This page is referenced in the [[Patent Thicket Literature Review]]
*This page is listed on the [[PTLR Core Papers]] page
==Reference==
*Ziedonis, R.H. (2004), "Don't fence me in: Fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms", Management Science, Vol. [http://www50, No.edegan6, pp.com/pdfs/Ziedonis%20(2004)%20804-%20Dont%20fence%20me%20in.pdf pdf]-820
@article{ziedonis2004don,
title={Don't fence me in: Fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms},
author={Ziedonis, R.H.},
journal={Management Science},
volume={50},
number={6},
pages={804--820},
year={2004},
abstract={How do firms avoid being “fenced in” by owners of patented technologies used, perhaps unknowingly, in the design or manufacture of their products? This paper examines the conditions under which firms expand their own portfolios of patents in response to potential hold-up problems in markets for technology. Combining insights from transactions cost theory with recent scholarship on intellectual property and its exchange, I predict firms will patent more aggressively than otherwise expected when markets for technology are highly fragmented (i.e., ownership rights to external technologies are widely distributed); this effect should be more pronounced for firms with large investments in technology-specific assets and under a strong legal appropriability regime. Although these characteristics of firms and their external environments have been highlighted in the theoretical literature, prior research has not explored the extent to which such factors interact to shape the patenting behavior of firms. To empirically test these hypotheses, I develop a citations-based “fragmentation index” and estimate the determinants of patenting for 67 U.S. semiconductor firms between 1980 and 1994. Accumulating exclusionary rights of their own may enable firms to safeguard their investments in new technologies while foregoing some of the costs and delays associated with ex ante contracting.},
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Measures, Empirical},
industry={},
thicket_stance={},
thicket_stance_extract={},
thicket_def={},
thicket_def_extract={},
tags={},
filename={Ziedonis (2004) - Dont Fence Me In.pdf}
}
==AbstractFile(s)==
How do firms avoid being "fenced in" by owners of patented technologies used, perhaps unknowingly, in the design or manufacture of their products? This paper examines the conditions under which firms expand their own portfolios of patents in response to potential hold-up problems in markets for technology. Combining insights from transactions cost theory with recent scholarship on intellectual property and its exchange, I predict firms will patent more aggressively than otherwise expected when markets for technology are highly fragmented *[[Media:Ziedonis (i.e., ownership rights to external technologies are widely distributed2004); this effect should be more pronounced for firms with large investments in technology-specific assets and under a strong legal appropriability regimeDont Fence Me In. Although these characteristics of firms and their external environments have been highlighted in pdf|Download the theoretical literature, prior research has not explored the extent to which such factors interact to shape the patenting behavior of firms. To empirically test these hypotheses, I develop a citationsPDF]]*[[:Image:Ziedonis (2004) -based "fragmentation index" and estimate the determinants of patenting for 67 U.S. semiconductor firms between 1980 and 1994. Accumulating exclusionary rights of their own may enable firms to safeguard their investments in new technologies while foregoing some of the costs and delays associated with ex ante contractingDont Fence Me In.pdf|Repository record]]
==Abstract==
==Background Facts== *There has been an 'unprecendented' surge in patenting in the US (1.5 million filed 1990-2003 (assumed), 170,000 in 20001 alone)*The literature usually assumes that How do firms have the right to make, use or sell the avoid being “fenced in” by owners of patented technologies they internalizeused, but there are challenges to assembling the rights to outside technologies.*The US spent $1b in lawsuits over 1991 patentsperhaps unknowingly, about a 1/3rd of the R&D in that year*There was a "propatent" shift in IP protection in the 1980's - the 1982 creation design or manufacture of their products? This paper examines the Court conditions under which firms expand their own portfolios of Appeals for the Federal Circuit. The CAFC was propatent:**It expended the boundaries of claims through its interpretation of scope**It raised evidentiary standards for challenges to validity**It was more willing to grant preliminary injunctions**It issued 'propatent' rulings Survey evidence suggest that '''primary reasons''' firms patents are:#to '''prevent rivals''' from patenting#to use patents in '''negotiations''' with owners of outside technologies#response to '''deter''' infringement lawsuits Note that to capture the economic value of an innovation is not mentioned. Instead, '''patents are used for trading''' potential hold- to gain favorable access to outside technologies or to reduce expected outflows up problems in licensing.  ==Theory Development== Optimal patent policy design is based upon the notion that s'''trong rights''' will '''induce sufficient levels of R&D investment''' (markets for the first inventor in a cummulative chain)technology. But '''patents''':*Are '''inherently difficult to value'''*Have blurry boundaries that are '''difficult to demarcate'''*Are such that parties in the "cummulative chain" may find it '''hard to identify existing underlying IP'''  Two theoretical problems include:#The costs associated with being '''held up'''#The '''diffuse entitlements problem''' - underlying IP might be held by a large number of disparate parties  ===Hold-up in IP Markets=== '''Hold-up''' occurs when one party is able to '''expropriate rents''' Combining insights from another. As per Williamson, hold-up requires '''relational-specific investments''' (and '''incomplete contracts''', which are implicit here). '''Transaction transactions cost theory''' predicts that firms will either '''internalize''' the problem (i.e. make rather than buy) or '''underinvest''' when the risk of expropriation is high. With patents there is an additional twist (due to their public goods like nature). A patent is a '''right to exclude''' - it does not guarantee the owner the right to use if use infringes with recent scholarship on the rights of others. Firms must consider the price they expect to pay to use technologies patented by others intellectual property and so should try to improve their '''ex-post bargaining''' positions. '''Ex ante''' a firm could try to '''invent around''' a patent to alleviate hold-up. This is only possible with knowledge of the hindering patent(s) ex-anteits exchange, which can not be gauranteed. If the hindering I predict firms will patent is '''discovered after''' the firm has made a '''relational-specific investment''', such as in technology to implement the patent that is difficult to redeploy, the firm can be '''held up'''. Ex ante soltuions are less feasible when a large number of exclusionary rights exist, and perhaps more importantly, aggressively than otherwise expected when these rights markets for technology are widely heldhighly fragmented (iHere the '''anti-commons therory''' - ''that a large number of exclusionary rights leads to underinvestment'' - is supplemented by the notion of the '''dispersion of rights''', not just the number. Assuming that the '''Coasian setting of zero transaction costs does not hold''' (and it shouldn't!), the nature of the dispersion of the rights will mattere.  With '''concentrated rights''', that is ownership rights held by only one or a small number of holders, the firm may:*Contact the owner and '''negotiate''' (alliance, joint venture or acquisition, or licensing etc).*Attempt to '''invent around''' the rights**The rights external technologies are more '''easily identified''' because they are concentrated (this is Ed's addition)**Infringement is more likely to be detected**The most valuable patents are easier to identify**The per-patent licensing cost should be reduced (only license the valuable ones, and through a single agreementwidely distributedHowever, if the rights are '''fragmented''':*'''Ex ante solutions may be infeasible'''**The '''costs''' of licensing would be '''higher''', as would any delays - many agreements and a need to identify the value of each and every patent (in part to determine the likelyhood of exclusion ex-post)  '''Institutions''' such as patent pools, cross-licensing agreements, and collective rights organizations will arise (have arisen) to bundle patents and '''reduce transaction costs'''. '''Acquisition(s)''' may be a valid strategy but ; this involves direct costs (of the acquisition) and indirect costs (unrealized gains from trade with specialized firms - though this appears a little dubious). One mechanism to mitigate hazards is to '''amass a larger patent portfolio''' - this '''improves ex-post bargaining''' by creating an "exchange of hostages" (as per Williamson). The threat of a reciprocal suit may ameliorate rent seeking behaviour.  ===Hypotheses=== '''Hypothesis 1''': The more fragmented the external technology market, the more aggressively firms will patent An '''aggressive strategy''' is particularly important when:*External technology markets are fragmented*The anticipated cost of being held up is large.  '''Hypothesis 2''': The effect of fragmentated external rights on incentives to patents will should be more pronounced among capital-intensive for firms. The paper uses '''capital-intensitivity as a proxy for the relational specific with large investments''' that can be held up. There is considerable rationale in the paper why this might be true particularly in the semitechnology-conductor industry (which is the subject of the data sample)specific assets and under a strong legal appropriability regime.  '''Hypothesis 3a''': The effect Although these characteristics of fragmented firms and their external rights on incentives will be stronger following the propatent shift environments have been highlighted in the US legal environment '''Hypothesis 3b''': The interaction effect between fragmented rights and capital-intensity will be greater in magnitude following the propatent shift in the US legal environment.  ==Measures== The paper constructs a '''fragmentation measure''' as follows (time subscripts are ignored): :<math>FRAG_i = 1 - \sum_{j=1}^J \left ( \frac{NBCITES_{ij}}{NBCITES_i}\right )^2\theoretical literature, \quad i \ne j\,</math>  This measure is then corrected for firms with few patents: :<math>\hat{F}_i = \left ( \frac{NBCITES_i}{NBCITES_{i-1}}\right ) \cdot FRAG_i\,</math>  where <math>NBCITES_i\,</math> is prior research has not explored the total number of citations extent to a patent assigned to a firm (on an annual basis)  There are '''two types of error inherenent''' in which such a measure:*Type 1: a citation is observed but there is no risk of infringement or no need factors interact to license*Type 2: There ia risk shape the patenting behavior of infrigement or a potential need to license but a citation is not observedfirms.  '''Capital intensity''' is measured as the deflated book-value of a firm's propertyTo empirically test these hypotheses, plant and equipment, normalized by the number of employees. Note that firm size is included as I develop a covariate citations-based “fragmentation index” and is estimate the number determinants of employees (logged)patenting for 67 U. The era in which the "new power of patents" was known, was defined to be 1985 onwards, after a series of important court casesS==Results== The paper runs a base model (without the key explanatory variables) first, to get a baseline propensity to patent.  Firms that have a capital intensive one standard deviation above the mean patent '''five times''' more aggressively in response to average levels of fragmentation, even after controlling for R&D semiconductor firms between 1980 and firm size1994. More importantly, capital-intensive firms do not patent more intensively '''unless''' they build upon fragmented technology pools. Increases in technological opportunity are discounted as an explantion - patenting in non-US jurisdictions is used as a measure. Possibly higher capital-intensive firms with higher fragmentation are also engaged in a broader range Accumulating exclusionary rights of alliances (e.g. R&D agreements with other their own may enable firms, universities, etc), which increases the efficiency of to safeguard their R&D. However, this is discounted investments in unreported results that interact R&D with fragmentation. Likewise new technologies while foregoing some firms may just be better - fixed of the costs and random effects models do not support this hypothesis.  Finally, it does appear that the propatenting environment had the hypothesized effect: stricter IP regimes increased the hold-up problemdelays associated with ex ante contracting.
Anonymous user

Navigation menu