Difference between revisions of "Untangling the Economics of Patent Thickets"

From edegan.com
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Line 2: Line 2:
 
|Has title=Patent Thicket Literature Review
 
|Has title=Patent Thicket Literature Review
 
|Has author=Ed Egan, David Teece
 
|Has author=Ed Egan, David Teece
 +
|Has RAs=Lauren Bass,
 
|Has paper status=Working paper
 
|Has paper status=Working paper
 
}}
 
}}
 
 
==The Paper==
 
==The Paper==
  

Revision as of 16:59, 22 June 2017

Academic Paper
Title Patent Thicket Literature Review
Author Ed Egan, David Teece
RAs Lauren Bass
Status Working paper
© edegan.com, 2016

The Paper

Latest version is:

\coauthoredprojects\Egan and Teece\McN-PatentThicket-Egan-092215.pdf

This file is posted at http://www.bakerinstitute.org/research/untangling-patent-thicket-literature

Definitions

Core Terms

A) Saturated Invention Spaces: The earliest definition of a patent thicket that we found is in Teece (1998), who points out a simple issue with patents. We refer to this as ‘saturated invention spaces’ and describe it as when a single firm, or a small number of firms, successfully patents an entire technological area. (p.15)

  • Imperfect competition: a small number of firms hold all possible patent rights in an area

Terms like “cluster”, “related”, “adjacent”, or “coherent group” to describe either patents or inventions. However, we also included several definitions that described patents as “minor” or “marginal” provided that there was no suggestion of bad faith

B) Diversely-held Complimentary Inputs (DHCI): 1) products require complementary patented inputs; 2) these inputs are diversely-held (i.e. held by N patent-holders); and 3) patent-holders set their license prices independently. (Shapiro, pg.17)

  • Coordination: patent holders determine licensing rates independently

“Diversely-held” and “complementary inputs,” or clear synonyms like “dispersed” or “fragmented” pertaining to ownership and “Cournot problem”, “multiple marginalization”, etc. in the context of licensing of patents held by multiple parties

C) Overlapping Patents:

  1. The second most common foundation for a patent thicket issue relies on overlapping patents. Patent overlaps can be horizontal (i.e. though patents that are largely adjacent to one another) or vertical (i.e. when patents are related through cumulative innovation). Horizontal overlaps arise because patent rights are imperfectly defined property rights. (p.20)
  2. Refinement patents and research tool patents could result in vertically overlapping patent rights (or at least contractual rights). (p.21)
  • Imperfectly defined property rights: wasteful duplication of licensing expenditure

Any sense of patent overlaps including “overlapping claims” or “similar claims”, and/or uncertainty over whether multiple patents may simultaneously be infringed

D) Gaming the Patent System: There are information asymmetries between a patent applicant and the patent office and a patent applicant may take some inappropriate action, for example by applying for a patent that is not novel or is obvious. Such an inappropriate action can impose costs on the patent office and may generate negative externalities, imposing costs on genuine innovators. We refer to this situation as ‘gaming the patent system’. (p.21)

  • Moral hazard: patent applicants take hidden action and impose costs on genuine innovators

Primarily descriptions of patents as “questionable” “dubious” “bad”, “likely invalid” and “junk,” and phrases congruent with “impeding genuine innovators” or “rent-seeking activities”, as well as other indications of bad faith

Modern Terms

E) Transaction Costs: All patent-based interactions, from application to licensing to litigation, are subject to transaction and search costs. Patent applications are subject to transaction costs in the form of prosecution costs and renewal (‘maintenance’) fees. These costs and fees are supposed to de-incentivize low value patents. However, they may also de-incentivize invention by small firms and individuals. (p.13)

F) Probabilistic Patents: Lemley and Shapiro (2005, 2006) emphasize that patents are ‘probabilistic’. They suggest that “there is no way to determine with certainty whether the patent is valid and infringed without litigating to judgment." Enforcement of patent rights - observing and redressing infringement of patent claims - is therefore both costly and uncertainty. (p.11)

G) Unspecified/Extended Use: Kiley (1992) claims that applying for a patent based on an inventive step that does not have a clearly articulated stand-alone commercial value creates economic inefficiencies. But often it can be difficult to foresee which particular use of an invention will be profitable and which won’t. (p.8)

H) Search Costs: Searching for relevant patents may impose material costs. Wang (2010) argues that this may be particularly burdensome for new entrants who need to develop suitable search capabilities. (p.13)

I) (Patent) Hold-up: The Federal Trade Commission (2011) provides the following definition of patent hold-up: “‘Hold-up’ describe[s] a patentee’s ability to extract a higher license fee after an accused infringer has sunk costs into implementing the patented technology than the patentee could have obtained at the time of [the accused infringer’s] design decisions.” However, some recent papers have stressed the obvious diametrically opposite problem. Langus et al. (2013), for example, point out that

“the licensee may often engage in a reverse hold up”. Reverse patent hold-up, loosely put, is where the accused infringer extracts zero (via infringing) license fee after the patent owner has sunk costs in developing :the patented technology and alleged infringement has taken place. Again, this occurs as patents are not self-enforcing. Implementers can simply use the invention covered by a patent and wait to get sued, using as :many diversionary tactics in the courts as is possible, knowing that it is hard, time-consuming, and expensive for a patentee to get an injunction. The judicial system is far from perfect; the patentee has few remedies :absent a courts intervention. (p.11-12)

J) Strategic Patents: Strategic patenting is sometimes defined as accumulating patents merely to achieve design freedom. These patents can be used as bargaining chips, rather than for their intrinsic value, and as such are largely welfare neutral, except in conjunction with transaction costs and cross- licensing agreements (discussed shortly). Much of the discussion of strategic patents takes place in the context of the patent thicket literature. (p.13)

“To obtain the rights to infringe patents held by external parties and to improve their leverage in negotiations with other patent owners, these firms amass larger patent portfolios of their own with which to trade.” – :Hall and Ziedonis (2001)

K) Hold-out: Hold-out can occur in the context of multilateral bargaining, for example when different products can be made out of different, diversely-held patented technologies. Farrell (2009) explains that when a partial agreement benefits the “nonparticipating (holdout) player”, self-interest and social welfare may not be aligned. (p.12-13)

Relative Definition Quotes

Shapiro: "a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology" (p.3-4)

Kiley: "Those operating at the beginnings of the road are most insistent on their right to nail down leverage that will remain formidable despite market place rejection of the uses to which they say their inventions may be put. The frank aim of these early stage workers is to control ultimate applications discovered by others." (p. 8)


Measures

Types

  1. Theory: Economic theory papers are largely concerned with the DHCI problem. (p.5)
  2. Empirical: Papers that drift towards first including overlapping patents along with DHCI, and then begin abandoning the usage of DCHI. (p.5)
  3. Discussion: It seems that economists favor DHCI and overlaps, cite Shapiro (2001) and do more theoretical work; whereas legal scholars favor overlaps, cite Heller and Eisenberg (1998) and provide discussion. (p.30)

Industries

  1. Basic Science: Basic research, which includes the commercialization of academic research, biotechnology, genetics, nanotechnology, and pharmaceuticals. (p.28)
  2. Complex Science: Complex product industries, which includes information and communications technology (aside from software and the internet but specifically including semiconductors), manufacturing, and sewing machines (which in the period of analysis of papers discussing it was a complex cutting-edge product). (p.28)
  3. Software / Bus. Method: An aggregate of firms focused on software, business methods, and the internet. (p.28)

Topics

  1. Effects on Academia: Overlapping patents are curiously related to basic science and the effects of patenting on academic research, both of which depend upon cumulative innovation. (p.30)
  2. Private Mechanism: Private arrangement papers discuss cross-licensing, patent pools, patent clearinghouses, patent collectives, FRAND licensing agreements, patent intermediaries (including NPEs), shared platforms, technology standards, and Standard Setting Organizations (SSOs). (p.27)
  3. Industry Commentary: There was also a distinct set of publications that engaged in industry commentary; commentary on the nanotechnology and genetics industries were particularly common. (p.27-28)
  4. IPR Reform: IPR reform papers suggest reforms to the nature of intellectual property rights, examine processes for granting patents at the patent office, and advocate approaches to patent-related transactions for anti-trust authorities. (p.27)
  5. Firm Strategy: Firm strategy papers provide strategic advice to firms regarding their intellectual property – they discuss the strategic implications of blocking patents, pre-emptive patenting, secrecy, ever-greening, avoiding willful infringement, engaging in Mexican standoffs, and other defensive or offensive patenting behaviors, as well the consequences of doings so on collaboration, industry structure (including entry), and the value of firms. (p.27)
  6. Patent Thickets: We suggest that one reason why papers implement definitions that are consistent with more than one economic issue is that many of the original definitions of patent thickets were made by analogy. Analogies face the risk of multiple possible interpretations. Shapiro (2001) is frequently quoted in the literature saying that patent thickets are “a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology". Shapiro’s analogy is compatible with all four of the most commonly discussed economic issues referred to as patent thickets. (p.3-4)

Publication Type

  1. Econ
  2. Law
  3. Science
  4. Policy Report
  1. Number of Authors
  2. Repeat Authors

Current List of Papers

Processed papers

Files

  • Current directory containing candidate papers
  • Processed BibTeX master file


Maybe Important Files

  • PTLRCore.bib - Might contain core BibTeX entries
  • PTLRDefinitions.pdf - useful to contrast conflicting definitions
  • PTLRBibliography.bib - Long list of citations
  • PTLR-HoldupQuotes.txt - List of complete quotes with citations
  • PTLR-PolicyRpts.txt - Short list of policy reports ranging from 2002 - 2013
  • PTLRUp.bib - Another bibliography, additions or subtractions unknown


.PL files

  • BibTucker.pl - location PTLRv2 & 3 folders
  • PTLRBibTeXReprocessing.pl - location PTLRv2 & 3 folders
  • temp.pl - location PTLRv2 folder
  • BibTuckerV20.pl - PTLRv3 folder
  • PLTROldTables.txt