Difference between revisions of "PTLR Annotated BibTeX Master"

From edegan.com
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Ed
imported>Andrew
 
(2 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 6: Line 6:
  
 
==The Master File==
 
==The Master File==
 
@article{aggarwal2009modes,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Modes of Cooperative R&D Commercialization by Start-Ups},
 
  author = {Aggarwal, Vikas A. and Hsu, David H.},
 
  journal = {Strategic Management Journal},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {30},
 
  number = {8},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Aug., 2009},
 
  pages = {pp. 835-864},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/20536081},
 
  ISSN = {01432095},
 
  abstract = {This study empirically examines the determinants of heterogeneous firm-level cooperative R&D commercialization strategies. While the volume of interfirm collaboration has increased dramatically in recent decades, the determinants of firm-level choices among alternate modes of such cooperative activity remain relatively understudied. We develop a conceptual model of factors determining collaborative mode choice at the organizational portfolio level. These factors include the firm-level appropriation environment, in which deal-level choices have portfolio-level spillover implications, as well as governance capabilities developed by the firm over time. Using a random sample of innovating biotechnology start-ups, we assemble a firm-year panel dataset that aggregates transaction-level collaboration data to the firm-year level, allowing us to characterize firms' portfolios of collaborative deals. We find broad empirical support for our model, suggesting that a firm's appropriation environment and governance capabilities strongly influence portfolio-level collaboration mode choices. In addition, we explore the implications of governance capability development, finding that experience with particular modes, as well as deviations from existing capabilities, impact firm valuation.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2009},
 
  publisher = {Wiley},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2009 Wiley},
 
  filename={Aggarwal Hsu (2009) - Modes Of Cooperative R And D Commercialization By Start Ups.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical Biotech
 
 
Biotech: all firms in Standard Industrial Classification
 
(SIC) codes 2833–2836 located in the United
 
States that have conducted an initial public offering
 
(IPO)17 in the past 25 years. From this list of
 
468 firms, we randomly select 117 for our sample.
 
 
A firm’s patent portfolio can enable the
 
firm to mitigate appropriation concerns that arise
 
across multiple deals. This occurs when patents
 
are not specific to an individual deal, but rather
 
apply across multiple technology commercialization
 
projects. Such an intellectual property portfolio
 
can thus act as a ‘patent thicket’ (Shapiro,
 
2000), making it more difficult for collaborative
 
partners to expropriate the innovating firm’s technology.
 
11 The degree of protection afforded by
 
such a portfolio will, of course, necessarily be
 
dependent on the degree to which patents are relevant
 
across multiple commercialization projects.
 
 
While the prior literature has discussed patent thickets in
 
the context of fragmented markets for intellectual property, we
 
conceptualize an analogous situation with the innovator holding
 
a stock of interrelated patents that deters potential expropriation
 
of a range of related products, a situation especially relevant
 
for start-up innovators, as most such firms confine their product
 
development to a single or small number of related products for
 
resource reasons.
 
 
 
@article{allison2003business,
 
  title={The Business Method Patent Myth},
 
  author={Allison, J.R. and Tiller, E.H.},
 
  journal={Berkeley Tech. LJ},
 
  volume={18},
 
  pages={987},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Allison Tiller (2003) - The Business Method Patent Myth.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Empirical: Business Method Patents
 
 
In other words, many closely related patents may cover a single product, making
 
it much more difficult for competitors to invent noninfringing substitutes. Patent
 
thickets increase the probability of “hold-up” licensing, that is, exercising the ability to
 
charge a premium for patent licenses in the case of technologies in which competitors
 
have already invested heavily. Id. A patent thicket is just one instance of portfolio value,
 
because a group of patents on related technologies can have a value greater than the sum
 
of its parts even if the patents do not create overlapping rights in the same product.
 
 
Our initial search for all patents issued from the beginning of 1990 to
 
the end of 1999 that included the terms “Internet or World Wide Web”
 
yielded over 9,000, most of which used these terms in an incidental
 
fashion (such as a cite to a piece of prior art on the Internet).149 Although a
 
survey of these patents found a few initially promising candidates in older
 
computer industry classifications such as 345, 365, 370, and 375, we
 
found by far the heaviest concentration in the newer 700-series “data
 
processing” or “electrical computer” classifications.150 In particular, most
 
contenders for inclusion appeared in Class 705, 707, and 709.151
 
 
 
@article{aoki2008promoting,
 
  title={Promoting access to intellectual property: patent pools, copyright collectives, and clearinghouses},
 
  author={Aoki, R. and Schiff, A.},
 
  journal={R\&d Management},
 
  volume={38},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={189--204},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Aoki Schiff (2008) - Promoting Access To Intellectual Property.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Pools, Collectives, Clearinghouses. ICT and Biotech.
 
 
In the context of patents, a proliferation of IP
 
rights may result in a ‘patent thicket’ (Shapiro,
 
2001) that can increase costs for downstream
 
activities such as cumulative innovation and the
 
development of new products that combine multiple
 
existing innovations.
 
 
For example, development of a new
 
genetic diagnostic test typically requires licenses
 
to a number of patents on gene sequences and
 
related technologies (Scherer, 2002). The greater
 
the number of licenses required, the greater the
 
cost of developing the new test. This paper is
 
concerned with ways in which these costs can be
 
reduced so that markets for technology can function
 
more efficiently.
 
 
@inproceedings{arundel2003strategic,
 
  title={Strategic patenting},
 
  author={Arundel, A. and Patel, P.},
 
  booktitle={Background report for the Trend Chart Policy Benchmarking Workshop" New Trends in IPR Policy},
 
  year={2003},
 
  filename={Arundel Patel (2003) - Strategic Patenting.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy
 
 
One of the worst-case outcomes of the patenting strategies of private firms is the
 
creation of an ‘anti-commons’ in which the necessary knowledge to conduct further
 
research is covered by a large number of patents held by a large number of firms. This
 
has been called a patent thicket, or a “dense web of overlapping intellectual property
 
rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize
 
new technology” (Shapiro, in press).
 
 
 
 
@article{balasubramanian2011what,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  Title = {What Happens When Firms Patent? New Evidence From U.S. Economic Census Data},
 
  author = {Balasubramanian, Natarajan and Sivadasan, Jagadeesh},
 
  journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {93},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {February 2011},
 
  pages = {pp. 126-146},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/23015924},
 
  ISSN = {00346535},
 
  abstract = {We build a new concordance between the NBER Patent Data and U.S. Census microdata and use it to examine what happens when firms patent. We find strong evidence that increases in patent stock are associated with increases in firm size, scope, and skill and capital intensity. We find somewhat weaker evidence that changes in patenting are positively correlated with changes in total factor productivity. We also analyze firsttime patentees and find similar effects following initial patent application. Together, these results suggest that patenting is indeed associated with real changes within firms, in particular with growth through increases in scope.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2011},
 
  publisher = {The MIT Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2011 The MIT Press},
 
  filename={Balasubramanian Sivadasan (2011) - What Happens When Firms Patent.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Cross industry, large scale, TFP
 
 
We find strong evidence that increases in patent stock are associated
 
with increases in firm size, scope, and skill and capital intensity. We
 
find somewhat weaker evidence that changes in patenting are positively
 
correlated with changes in total factor productivity. We also analyze firsttime
 
patentees and find similar effects following initial patent application.
 
Together, these results suggest that patenting is indeed associated with real
 
changes within firms, in particular with growth through increases in scope.
 
 
@article{baluch2005re,
 
  title={In re Kumar: the first nanotech patent case in the federal circuit},
 
  author={Baluch, A.S. and Radomsky, L. and Maebius, S.B.},
 
  journal={Nanotech. L. \& Bus.},
 
  volume={2},
 
  pages={344},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Baluch Radomsky Maebius (2005) - In Re Kumar The First Nanotech Patent Case In The Federal Circuit.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Nanotech
 
 
For example, a claim in a later patent may cover a new and nonobvious improvement on a basic invention
 
claimed in an earlier patent. In this case, both patents would properly cover the improved product. A large number
 
of patents containing overlapping claims which cover the same product are often referred to as a "patent thicket."
 
 
 
@article{bargill2003thevalue,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {The Value of Giving Away Secrets},
 
  author = {Bar-Gill, Oren and Gideon Parchomovsky},
 
  journal = {Virginia Law Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {89},
 
  number = {8},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Dec., 2003},
 
  pages = {pp. 1857-1895},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/3202368},
 
  ISSN = {00426601},
 
  abstract = {},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2003},
 
  publisher = {Virginia Law Review},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2003 Virginia Law Review},
 
  filename={BarGill Parchomovsky (2003) - The Value Of Giving Away Secrets.pdf}
 
}
 
Law: Cummulative Innovation -> give away rights can be best
 
 
In growingn umbersf, irmse lect to foregop atentp rotection,
 
a nd choose instead to publishp otentiallyp atentabler esearchf
 
inding
 
 
Indeed, from an ex post perspective, the original inventor would prefer a broader patent. The ex post perspective is deceptive, how- ever, since it presumes the existence of the cumulative invention- an existence which cannot be taken for granted. Generally, the cumulative inventor would need to sink substantial development costs before she can approach the original inventor and bargain for a license. Therefore, if a broad patent protects the original inven- tion and, consequently, the cumulative inventor expects to be held- up in the bargaining stage, she might decide to forego the cumula- tive invention altogether. Critically, the breadth of the original pat- ent determines the division of surplus between the original and
 
cumulative inventors.5 If the share that the cumulative inventor ex- pects to receive does not cover her ex ante development costs, then the cumulative invention will not be developed in the first place. This result is clearly detrimental not only to the cumulative inven- tor, but also to the original inventor
 
 
 
@article{baron2010patent,
 
  title={Patent quality and value in discrete and cumulative innovation},
 
  author={Baron, J. and Delcamp, H.},
 
  journal={CERNA Working Paper},
 
  number={2010-07},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Baron Delcamp (2010) - Patent Quality And Value In Discrete And Cumulative Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Patent quality and value in discrete vs. cummulative innovation
 
 
Patent thickets are webs of overlapping and mutually blocking patents held by different
 
owners. Mutually blocking patent rights result from cumulative innovation, where no
 
technological component can be marketed individually without the technological
 
complements potentially protected by patent rights of different companies.
 
 
@article{baron2010strategic,
 
  title={Strategic inputs into patent pools},
 
  author={Baron, J. and Delcamp, H.},
 
  journal={Cerna working paper},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Baron Delcamp (2010) - Strategic Inputs Into Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Emprical Pools
 
 
The patent thicket describes a situation in which
 
holders of different patents that are all necessary for complying with a standard mutually block
 
each other in the implementation of the standard.
 
 
We have produced a unique database of 7 patent pools with 8046 patent observations: DVD6C,
 
MPEG2, MPEG4 Systems, MPEG4 Visuals, AVC H/264, IEEE 1394 and DVB-T.
 
 
@inproceedings{baron2011patent,
 
  title={Patent Pools and Patent Inflation},
 
  author={Baron, J. and Pohlmann, T.},
 
  booktitle={Conference Proceedings: 4th ZEW Conference on the Economics of Innovation and Patenting},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={Baron Pohlmann (2011) - Patent Pools And Patent Inflation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical Pools
 
 
Building upon theoretical propositions drawn from
 
Dequiedt and Versaevel (2007) and a database of 64.619 declarations of essential patents
 
to major international Standard Developing Organizations (SDO), we investigate how
 
patent pools influence the number of patents on a standard over time
 
 
Shapiro, 2001 def.
 
 
@article{barpujari2010patent,
 
  title={The patent regime and nanotechnology: issues and challenges},
 
  author={Barpujari, I.},
 
  journal={Journal of Intellectual Property Rights},
 
  volume={15},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={206--213},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Barpujari (2010) - The Patent Regime And Nanotechnology Issues And Challenges.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Nanotech
 
 
Building upon theoretical propositions drawn from
 
Dequiedt and Versaevel (2007) and a database of 64.619 declarations of essential patents
 
to major international Standard Developing Organizations (SDO), we investigate how
 
patent pools influence the number of patents on a standard over time
 
 
 
 
@article{bawa2007nanotechnology,
 
  title={Nanotechnology patent proliferation and the crisis at the US Patent Office},
 
  author={Bawa, R.},
 
  journal={Alb. LJ Sci. \& Tech.},
 
  volume={17},
 
  pages={699},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Bawa (2007) - Nanotechnology Patent Proliferation And The Crisis At The Us Patent Office.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Nanotech Discussion
 
 
Not Copyable
 
 
 
 
 
 
@article{bessen2003patent,
 
  title={Patent thickets: Strategic patenting of complex technologies},
 
  author={Bessen, J.},
 
  journal={Available at SSRN 327760},
 
  year={2003},
 
  filename={Bessen (2003) - Patent Thickets Strategic Patenting Of Complex Technologies.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ (weak): Theory of thickets
 
 
These occur when each
 
product may involve many patents, in contrast with the one-to-one correspondence between
 
products and patents that is assumed in the patent race literature. Recent commentators suggest
 
that lower patenting standards encourage patent thickets, creating difficulties for innovators (see
 
Gallini, 2002, for a review). When innovators must negotiate with large numbers of
 
patentholders, they may face excessive transaction costs (Heller and Eisenberg, 1998), “holdup,”
 
and problems of vertical monopoly (Shapiro, 2001).
 
 
@article{bessen2008value,
 
  title={The value of US patents by owner and patent characteristics},
 
  author={Bessen, J.},
 
  journal={Research Policy},
 
  volume={37},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={932--945},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Bessen (2008) - The Value Of Us Patents By Owner And Patent Characteristics.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Thicketing may add to patent value
 
 
A
 
larger number of patents may simply reflect that an owner is protecting more inventions with patents,
 
or that owner may be “fencing” off the technology by patenting possible substitute technologies or
 
building a patent “thicket.”
 
 
@article{bergman2007global,
 
  title={The global stem cell patent landscape: implications for efficient technology transfer and commercial development},
 
  author={Bergman, K. and Graff, G.D.},
 
  journal={Nature biotechnology},
 
  volume={25},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={419--424},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Nature Publishing Group},
 
  filename={Bergman Graff (2007) - The Global Stem Cell Patent Landscape.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: Stem Cells (could give rise to thickets)
 
 
Given the particular characteristics of stem
 
cells as a broadly enabling technology, many
 
expect the field to be particularly susceptible
 
to the emergence of a patent thicket8–13, also
 
known in property rights theory as an ‘anticommons’
 
14. In a patent thicket, the existence
 
of many overlapping patent claims can cause
 
uncertainty about freedom to operate, impose
 
multiple layers of transaction costs and stack
 
royalty payments beyond levels that can be
 
supported by the value of single innovations.
 
By blocking pathways to market and dampening
 
investor interest in commercialization,
 
a patent thicket has the potential to slow and
 
skew the overall development of new technical
 
applications.
 
 
 
@article{blind2009influence,
 
  title={The influence of strategic patenting on companies’ patent portfolios},
 
  author={Blind, K. and Cremers, K. and Mueller, E.},
 
  journal={Research Policy},
 
  volume={38},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={428--436},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Blind Cremers Mueller (2009) - The Influence Of Strategic Patenting On Companies Patent Portfolios.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Effects of strategic patenting
 
 
Furthermore, an observed offensive
 
blocking strategy results in frequent oppositions and rather limited citations of a
 
company’s patent portfolio. Such a strategy could also lead to “patent thickets”,
 
 
@article{braun2007barriers,
 
  title={Barriers to user innovation: moving towards a paradigm of'licence to innovate'?},
 
  author={Braun, V. and Herstatt, C.},
 
  journal={International Journal of Technology, Policy and Management},
 
  volume={7},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={292--303},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Inderscience},
 
  filename={Braun Herstatt (2007) - Barriers To User Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Discussion based on seed-breeding
 
 
An investigation of the barriers that users face when attempting to innovate is nevertheless lacking completely. In this paper, we attempt to fill this gap by discussing various factors that can prevent users from innovating. The evolution of the seed-breeding industry will be used for illustration purposes. We will argue that the barriers to user innovation seem to be progressing, potentially indicating that a paradigm change may be imminent.
 
 
This refers to an overlapping set of IPRs, which requires those seeking to commercialise new technologies to obtain licences (Shapiro, 2001). It exists in many industries, such as in semiconductors and biotechnology (Hall and Ziedonis, 2001; Heller and Eisenberg, 1998).
 
 
@article{brenner2009optimal,
 
  title={Optimal formation rules for patent pools},
 
  author={Brenner, S.},
 
  journal={Economic Theory},
 
  volume={40},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={373--388},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Springer},
 
  filename={Brenner (2009) - Optimal Formation Rules For Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of pool formation
 
 
No real mention of thickets but builds off complementary patents
 
 
@article{burk2003policy,
 
  title={Policy levers in patent law},
 
  author={Burk, D.L. and Lemley, M.A.},
 
  journal={Va. L. Rev.},
 
  volume={89},
 
  pages={1575},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Burk Lemley (2003) - Policy Levers In Patent Law.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory - Direct discussion of thicket problem
 
 
Closely related to the problem of complementarity is the prob- lem of horizontal overlaps between patents.122 Patents are fre- quently broader than the products the inventors actually make. Multiple patents often cover the same ground, sometimes as an in- tentional result of the patent system"' and sometimes because pat- ents regularly issue that are too broad or tread on the prior art.'24 Various parties may be able to lay claim to the same technologies or to aspects of the same technology. Carl Shapiro has termed this overlap of patent claims the "patent thicket." 125
 
 
@article{calderini2006standardisation,
 
  title={Standardisation in the ICT sector: The (complex) interface between antitrust and intellectual property},
 
  author={Calderini, M. and Giannaccari, A.},
 
  journal={Econ. Innov. New Techn.},
 
  volume={15},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={543--567},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Taylor \& Francis},
 
  filename={Calderini Giannaccari (2006) - Standardisation In The Ict Sector.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Policy: Discussion: Stardardization in ICT
 
 
It is obvious that the characteristics of the aforementioned technological paradigm determine
 
a complex network of intertwined property rights to which a company intending to
 
develop a new product must access. This network is defined a patent thicket (Shapiro, 2001).
 
A patent thicket consists of a number of adjacent and overlapping property rights, which
 
impose on whoever wishes to use certain intermediate goods to ask for licenses from several
 
patent holders. Obviously, this frequently results in high monetary and transaction costs. The
 
entity of such costs is often so great as to discourage innovative activity in the downstream
 
phases of the innovation process. This finding represents a real turning over of one of the
 
funding concepts of the economics of intellectual property rights, according to which a tighter
 
enforcement of intellectual property rights favours innovative activity. Contrarily, in the presence
 
of cumulative and systemic innovative activities, there are reasons to believe that too
 
strict intellectual property rights would lead to perverse effects on innovative activity within
 
the industry.
 
 
@article{calderini2004intellectual,
 
  title={Intellectual property rights as strategic assets: the case of European patent opposition in the telecommunications industry},
 
  author={Calderini, M. and Scellato, G.},
 
  journal={CESPRI, Cen tre for Research on Innovation and Internationalisation, Universita'Bocconi, Working Paper},
 
  volume={158},
 
  year={2004},
 
  filename={Calderini Scellato (2004) - Intellectual Property Rights As Strategic Assets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Discussion: Close to Mexican Standoff
 
 
We suggest that in an industry characterised
 
by strong technological complementarities the distribution of patent rights may induce
 
situations of mutual hold-up among innovators. The risk of retaliation through countersuits
 
represents a credible threat that can eventually favour the instauration of collusive
 
behaviours. Our results confirm this hypothesis, since the occurrence of patent
 
oppositions among large incumbents is significantly lower than industry average.
 
 
No explicit definition.
 
 
 
 
@article{carnabuci2009knowledge,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Knowledge Specialization, Knowledge Brokerage and the Uneven Growth of Technology Domains},
 
  author = {Carnabuci, Gianluca and Bruggeman, Jeroen},
 
  journal = {Social Forces},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {88},
 
  number = {2},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {December 2009},
 
  pages = {pp. 607-641},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/40645818},
 
  ISSN = {00377732},
 
  abstract = {Why do certain domains of knowledge grow fast while others grow slowly or stagnate? Two distinct theoretical arguments hold that knowledge growth is enhanced by knowledge specialization and knowledge brokerage. Based on the notion of recombinant knowledge growth, we show that specialization and brokerage are opposing modes of knowledge generation, the difference between them lying in the extent to which homogeneous vs. heterogeneous input ideas get creatively recombined. Accordingly, we investigate how both modes of knowledge generation can enhance the growth of technology domains. To address this question, we develop an argument that reconciles both specialization and brokerage into a dynamic explanation. Our contention is that specializing in an increasingly homogeneous set of input ideas is both more efficient and less risky than brokering knowledge. Nevertheless, specializing implies progressively exhausting available recombinant possibilities, while brokerage creates new ones. Hence, technology domains tend to grow faster when they specialize, but the more specialized they become, the more they need knowledge brokerage to grow. We cast out our argument into five hypotheses that predict how growth rates vary across technology domains.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2009},
 
  publisher = {Oxford University Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2009 Social Forces, University of North Carolina Press},
 
  filename={Carnabuci Bruggeman (2009) - Knowledge Specialization Knowledge Brokerage.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Soci: Theory and empirics
 
 
Might provide an interesting counter to the measures...
 
 
the present study extends our understanding of how public technological knowledge accumulate
 
Our analysis showed that the process of recombinant growth driving the accumulation of public technological knowledge is far from combinatorially unconstrained. Rather, at any point in time, the rate of future accumulation of public technological knowledge is affected in important and predictable ways by the extent to which the body of accumulated prior knowledge in a technology domain is specialize
 
 
@article{carrier2002antitrust,
 
  title={Why Antitrust Should Defer to the Intellectual Property Rules of Standard-Setting Organizations: A Commentary on Teece \& (and) Sherry},
 
  author={Carrier, M.A.},
 
  journal={Minn. L. Rev.},
 
  volume={87},
 
  pages={2019},
 
  year={2002},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Carrier (2002) - Why Antitrust Should Defer To The Intellectual Property Rules Of SSOs.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Law (Commentary on Teece/Sherry).
 
 
No definition of thickets.
 
 
 
 
 
@article{carrier2012roadmap,
 
  title={A Roadmap to the Smartphone Patent Wars and FRAND Licensing},
 
  author={Carrier, M.},
 
  journal={CPI Antitrust Chronicle},
 
  volume={2},
 
  year={2012},
 
  filename={Carrier (2012) - A Roadmap To The Smartphone Patent Wars And Frand Licensing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Smartphone wars (short)
 
 
No def
 
 
@article{choi2005live,
 
  title={Live and let live: A tale of weak patents},
 
  author={Choi, J.P.},
 
  journal={Journal of the European Economic Association},
 
  volume={3},
 
  number={2-3},
 
  pages={724--733},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Choi (2005) - Live And Let Live A Tale Of Weak Patents.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Substitute patents
 
 
The lack of rigorous scrutiny in the examination process - in conjunction
 
with the recent explosion of patents granted - has led to a serious concern that
 
the current patent system may impede, rather than promote, innovation by creating
 
a "patent thicket" (Shapiro 2001; Gallini 2002; Bessen 2003).
 
 
 
 
@article{clark2008fragmented,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Fragmented Property Rights and Incentives for R&D},
 
  author = {Clark, Derek J. and Konrad, Kai A.},
 
  journal = {Management Science},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {54},
 
  number = {5},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {May, 2008},
 
  pages = {pp. 969-981},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/20122444},
 
  ISSN = {00251909},
 
  abstract = {Where product innovation requires several complementary patents, fragmented property rights can limit firms' willingness to invest in R&D. We consider the research intensity in multiple simultaneous R&D contests and how it depends on whether firms already hold relevant patents as well as the availability of an option to invent around. A measure of technological uncertainty is also analyzed. The multiple patent product involves an important hold-up problem that can reduce the overall R&D effort. Invent-around options moderate this problem. We also analyze targeted equilibria in which the aim of R&D can be to hold up a rival.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2008},
 
  publisher = {INFORMS},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2008 INFORMS},
 
  filename={Clark Konrad (2008) - Fragmented Property Rights And Incentives For R And D.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of cummulative innovation where fragmentation is endogeneous?
 
 
Complementarity of multiple patents has been identified
 
recently—by academics and industry practitioners—
 
as a potential problem, particularly in
 
biotechnology and other nascent industries based on
 
complex technologies. We have considered the incentives
 
for cumulative R&D effort if firms need several
 
complementary patent rights for producing multicomponent
 
products. Complementarity weakens the
 
incentives to invest in R&D effort. Intuitively, when
 
many complementary patents are needed to produce
 
a particular multicomponent good, a firm will very
 
likely fail to obtain all patents even if it invests heavily
 
in each of the single patent contests. At the same
 
time, holding a single patent secures the firm veto
 
power, and its payoff is therefore the same whether
 
it holds one, two, or even all but one of the patents.
 
This makes it less worthwhile to spend much effort
 
trying to win all the simultaneous contests. This effect
 
is strengthened if there is technological uncertainty
 
regarding whether each single patented innovation is
 
technically feasible and is weakened if patents have a
 
commercial value apart from the complementary use
 
in the multicomponent application.
 
When some firms already hold some patents in
 
their portfolios and others do not, this yields some
 
secure payoff to the leading firms. Although this is
 
good news for owners of firms that already hold large
 
stocks of patents, such stocks also yield a disincentive
 
for these leading firms to invest in ongoing patent
 
contests, unless only one patent remains unwon.
 
With a large number of further patents, the leading
 
firms are discouraged from participating in these
 
contests. The reason for this discouragement effect is
 
very different from Arrow’s well-known replacement
 
effect by which a new, superior patent invalidates
 
an incumbent firm’s existing one. Instead, the strategic
 
game becomes asymmetric because the firm that
 
has a nonempty portfolio still needs to win all further
 
patents to make the multicomponent product as
 
a monopolist, whereas the competing firm needs to
 
win only one of these further patents to secure some
 
of the monopoly profit.
 
 
@article{clarkson2004objective,
 
  title={Objective Identification of Patent Thickets: A Network Analytic Approach},
 
  author={Clarkson, G.},
 
  journal={Harvard Business School Doctoral Thesis},
 
  year={2004},
 
  filename={Clarkson (2004) - Objective Identification Of Patent Thickets A Network Analytic Approach.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory and cases: CORE THICKET PAPER
 
 
Despite all that has been written about patent thickets,2 an objective methodology for
 
verifying the existence of a patent thicket has never been developed. Throughout the last 150
 
years, however, organizations have stumbled into a number of patent thickets and have
 
occasionally responded by constructing patent pools, which this paper defines as organizational
 
structures where multiple firms collectively aggregate patent rights into a package for licensing,
 
either among themselves or to any potential licensees irrespective of membership in the pool.
 
Such collaboration among technologically competing firms, however, has often encountered
 
difficulty from an antitrust standpoint, even if the formation of the pool is pro-competitive.
 
 
@article{clarkson2005patent,
 
  title={Patent informatics for patent thicket detection: a network analytic approach for measuring the density of patent space},
 
  author={Clarkson, G.},
 
  journal={Academy of Management, Honolulu},
 
  year={2005},
 
  filename={Clarkson (2005) - Patent Informatics For Patent Thicket Detection.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
Discusses measures etc. Review in detail.
 
 
@article{clarkson2006problem,
 
  title={The problem of patent thickets in convergent technologies},
 
  author={Clarkson, G. and DeKorte, D.},
 
  journal={Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences},
 
  volume={1093},
 
  number={1},
 
  pages={180--200},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Clarkson DeKorte (2006) - The Problem Of Patent Thickets In Convergent Technologies.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion with network measures: CORE PAPER
 
 
Patent thickets are unintentionally dense webs of overlapping
 
intellectual property rights owned by different companies that can
 
retard progress.
 
 
@article{cockburn2006entry,
 
  title={Entry and Patenting in the Software Industry},
 
  author={Cockburn, I.M. and MacGarvie, M.J.},
 
  year={2006},
 
  journal={NBER Working Paper},
 
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Cockburn MacGarvie (2006) - Entry And Patenting In The Software Industry.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
Many firms, nonetheless, acquire large portfolios
 
of patents, and even where the primary motivation
 
for doing this goes beyond the potential to
 
exclude competitors, the impact of an accumulated
 
patent “thicket” on entry costs may be substantial
 
(see Shapiro 2001 for a definition of patent thickets).
 
 
 
@article{cockburn2009patents,
 
  title={Patents, Thickets and the Financing of Early-Stage Firms: Evidence from the Software Industry},
 
  author={Cockburn, I.M. and MacGarvie, M.J.},
 
  journal={Journal of Economics \& Management Strategy},
 
  volume={18},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={729--773},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Cockburn MacGarvie (2009) - Patents Thickets And The Financing Of Early Stage Firms.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
In this paper we attempt to characterize the extent to which entrants into a software
 
market at any given point in time face a patent “thicket”—i.e. a “a dense web of overlapping
 
intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually
 
commercialize new technology”3—and evaluate the impact of patent thickets on the interaction
 
between new software ventures and capital markets.
 
 
@article{cockburn2011entry,
 
  title={Entry and Patenting in the Software Industry},
 
  author={Cockburn, I.M. and Macgarvie, M.J.},
 
  journal={Management science},
 
  volume={57},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={915--933},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences},
 
  filename={Cockburn Macgarvie (2011) - Entry And Patenting In The Software Industry.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Revised version of above (only keep above if different)
 
 
@article{cockburn2010patent,
 
  title={Patent thickets, licensing and innovative performance},
 
  author={Cockburn, I.M. and MacGarvie, M.J. and M{\"u}ller, E.},
 
  journal={Industrial and Corporate Change},
 
  volume={19},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={899--925},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Oxford Univ Press},
 
  filename={Cockburn MacGarvie Muller (2010) - Patent Thickets Licensing And Innovative Performance.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
Defined by Shapiro (2001) as “a dense web...
 
 
@misc{cockburn2007patents,
 
  title={Patents and the Survival of Internet-related IPOs},
 
  author={Cockburn, I.M. and Wagner, S.},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA},
 
  filename={Cockburn Wagner (2007) - Patents And The Survival Of Internet Related Ipos.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
DOES NOT MENTION THICKETS!!! But the results do not support thickets in internet-software firms.
 
 
@techreport{cohen2000protecting,
 
  title={Protecting their intellectual assets: Appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not)},
 
  author={Cohen, W.M. and Nelson, R.R. and Walsh, J.P.},
 
  year={2000},
 
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Cohen Nelson Walsh (2000) - Protecting Their Intellectual Assets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Why firms patent
 
 
For example, the building of patent fences can be carried to the extreme
 
noted by Scherer [1980] and others to the point of creating "patent thickets" that foster
 
broader monopolies than anticipated by patent policy which in turn impede entry and the
 
innovation that may accompany it.
 
 
Our data do not show the degree to which patent portfolio races distort the nature
 
of R&D incentives or lead to socially wasteful outcomes, or whether such portfolio races
 
or patent thickets actually block entry. Nor do they indicate whether fee stacking or the
 
breakdown of negotiations in complex technology industries have ever undermined the
 
commercialization of innovation. The data do suggest, however, that the potential for
 
such outcomes may be more pervasive than previously thought.
 
 
@incollection{cohen2008real,
 
  title={Real impediments to academic biomedical research},
 
  author={Cohen, W.M. and Walsh, J.P.},
 
  booktitle={Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 8},
 
  pages={1--30},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={University of Chicago Press},
 
  filename={Cohen Walsh (2008) - Real Impediments To Academic Biomedical Research.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Academic research anticommons problems
 
 
Although their focus is largely on com
 
mercial projects, Heller and Eisenberg (1998) and Shapiro (2000) suggest
 
that the patenting of a broad range of research tools that researchers
 
need to do their work has spawned "patent thickets" that may make the
 
acquisition of licenses and other rights too burdensome to permit the
 
pursuit of what should otherwise be scientifically and socially worth
 
while research, (engendering a tragedy of the "anticommons" [Heller
 
and Eisenberg 1998]).15
 
 
We do find restrictions
 
imposed
 
on the flow of information and materials across biomedical researchers.
 
While patents play
 
some role, they
 
are not determinative. What appears to mat
 
ter are both academic and commercial incentives and effective excludability. Ex
 
clusion is rarely associated with the existence of a patent in academic settings, but
 
is more
 
readily achieved through secrecy or not sharing research materials.
 
 
@misc{competition2008pharmaceutical,
 
  title={Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry-Preliminary Report},
 
  author={Competition, DG},
 
  year={2008},
 
  filename={Competition (2008) - Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry Preliminary Report.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Pharmaceuticals
 
 
One commonly applied strategy is filing numerous patents for the same medicine
 
(forming so called "patent clusters" or "patent thickets"). Documents gathered in the
 
course of the inquiry confirm that an important objective of this strategy is to delay or
 
block the market entry of generic medicines. In this respect the inquiry finds that
 
individual blockbuster medicines are protected by up to 1,300 patents and/or pending
 
patent applications EU-wide and that, as mentioned above, certain patent filings occur
 
very late in the life cycle of a medicine.
 
 
@article{cotter2008patent,
 
  title={Patent Holdup, Patent Remedies, and Antitrust Responses},
 
  author={Cotter, T.F.},
 
  journal={J. Corp. L.},
 
  volume={34},
 
  pages={1151},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Cotter (2008) - Patent Holdup Patent Remedies And Antitrust Responses.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Definition of patent holdup (and ambush)
 
 
Doesn't mention thickets except in a footnote.
 
 
@article{cowin2007policy,
 
  title={Policy options for the improvement of the European patent system},
 
  author={Cowin, R. and Van der Eijck, W. and Lissoni, F. and Lotz, P. and Van Overwalle, G. and Schovsbo, J.},
 
  journal={Scientific Technology Options Assessment (STOA) of the European Parliament},
 
  year={2007},
 
  filename={Cowin (2007) - Policy Options For The Improvement Of The European Patent System.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: How to reform patent system. Focus on thickets
 
 
The sectors which are most affected by this phenomenon, at least in the US, are those whose
 
process and product innovations rely upon complex technologies where an individual piece of
 
equipment is the result of a very large number of components, all susceptible to patent
 
protection. Here, the recent boom in patenting observed by many researchers is largely
 
explained not by a firms’ drive to innovate more than before, but by a need to accumulate
 
large enough “patent thickets”. These patent thickets work as a sort of insurance against
 
possible legal actions from other companies. They are in effect therefore, a kind of defensive
 
manoeuvre.
 
 
@article{csardi2007modeling,
 
  title={Modeling innovation by a kinetic description of the patent citation system},
 
  author={Cs{\'a}rdi, G. and Strandburg, K.J. and Zal{\'a}nyi, L. and Tobochnik, J. and {\'E}rdi, P.},
 
  journal={Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications},
 
  volume={374},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={783--793},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Csardi (2007) - Modeling Innovation By A Kinetic Description Of The Patent Citation System.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Physics: Patent Citation Networks
 
 
Since 1991, preferential attachment
 
in the patent system has become increasingly
 
strong, indicating that patents are more and more stratified,
 
with fewer and fewer of the patents receiving more
 
and more of the citations. A few very important, perhaps
 
“pioneer”, patents seem to dominate the citations.
 
This trend may be consistent with fears of an increasing
 
patent “thicket”, in which more and more patents
 
are issued on minor technical advances in any given area.
 
These technically dense patents must be cited by patents
 
that build upon or distinguish them directly, thus requiring
 
that more citations be made, but few of them will be
 
of sufficient significance to merit citation by any but the
 
most closely related patents. Further work will be needed
 
to understand this change in citation network kinetics.
 
 
@article{denicolo2007do,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Do Patents Over-Compensate Innovators?},
 
  author = {Denicolò, Vincenzo},
 
  journal = {Economic Policy},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {22},
 
  number = {52},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Oct., 2007},
 
  pages = {pp. 679+681-729},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/4502213},
 
  ISSN = {02664658},
 
  abstract = {Is the current level of patent protection too high or too low? To address this issue, this paper reformulates the theoretical analysis of the optimal level of patent protection to take into account the empirical findings of the innovation production function literature. This literature finds a strong relationship between R&D spending and inventions and estimates an elasticity of the supply of inventions of 0.5 or more. Thepaper then assesses the current level of patent protection, exploiting estimates of the private and social returns to R&D taken from the empirical literature and other available sources. Although more research is needed for a more precise assessment, the evidence available suggests that patents do not overcompensate innovators.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2007},
 
  publisher = {Wiley on behalf of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, and the Maison des Sciences de l'Homme},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2007 Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies and Maison des Sciences de l'Homme},
 
  filename={Denicolo (2007) - Do Patents Over Compensate Innovators.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: 'Correct' allocation of returns to patent-holders
 
 
T. his literaturfien ds a strongr elationshibpe tweenR &D
 
spendinagn di nventionasn de stimateasn elasticitoyf thes upplyo f inventionosf
 
0.5 orm oreT. hepapetrh ena ssessetsh ec urrenlet veol f patentprotectieoxnp, loiting
 
estimateos f thep rivatea nds ocialr eturntso R&D takenfr om the empirical
 
literaturaen d othera vailables ourcesA. lthoughm orer esearcihs needefdo r a
 
morpe recisea ssessmentth, ee videncaev ailablseu ggesttsh atp atentsd o noto vercompensaitnen
 
ovators.
 
 
In certain industries, such as telecommunications and biotechnology, production of
 
new products often requires many complementary innovative components that are
 
owned by different firms.17 The proliferation and fragmentation of intellectual property
 
rights creates a 'patent thicket' that is often viewed as an obstacle to innovation.
 
Two main problems may emerge. First, a proliferation of patents held by different
 
owners increases transaction costs and might even prevent manufacturers from
 
obtaining the right to develop the new products, creating the tragedy of the anticommons
 
(Heller and Eisenberg, 1998). Second, with complementary patents there
 
may be a problem of Cournot complements (Shapiro, 2001) that increases the
 
deadweight loss to profit ratio D/17. How serious those problems are is a matter of
 
controversy,8
 
 
@article{devlin2009indeterminism,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Indeterminism and the Property-Patent Equation},
 
  author = {Devlin, Alan},
 
  journal = {Yale Law & Policy Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {28},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {fall 2009},
 
  pages = {pp. 61-106},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/27871287},
 
  ISSN = {07408048},
 
  abstract = {},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2009},
 
  publisher = {Yale Law & Policy Review, Inc.},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2009 Yale Law & Policy Review, Inc.},
 
  filename={Devlin (2009) - Indeterminism And The Property Patent Equation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory: Comparison of real and intellectual property rights
 
 
Property rights advocates further note that such fears such as irrational hold-out?most often voiced in the con text of patent thickets and experimental use?are not supported by empirical evidence.34 Instead, strong, overlapping property rights give rise to their own solution through patent pools, portfolio cross-licenses, standard-setting organi zations (SSOs), and invent-around.35
 
See F. Scott Kieff, Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inven tions, 85 Minn. L. Rev. 697, 719-27 (2001) (arguing that patents do not create a hold-out problem but in fact promote innovation and commercialization).
 
See, e.g., Daniel F. Spulber, Unlocking Technology: Antitrust and Innovation, 4 J. Competition L. & Econ. 915, 963 (2008). Patent pools are entities that accumu late and license blocking patents. They serve a valuable role in bypassing the un desirable economic phenomenon of royalty stacking, which can hinder or even prevent the commercialization of technologies that require the use of intellectual property-protected information. Sometimes a small number of companies that possess large patent portfolios can achieve the same result by cross-licensing one another.
 
 
More fundamentally still, the innumerable overlapping patents in certain high tech fields create an impenetrable "thicket" that frustrates quixotic conceptions of Coasian bargaining and acts only as an anticommons that paradoxically fore closes innovation.200 One's exclusion of another from his land is isolated; a sin gle patentee's ability to enjoin production of a semiconductor chip that impli cates thousands of patents creates powerful negative externalities.201 Given such distinctions, many view the worlds of patent law and traditional property as sufficiently distinct to be unworthy of direct analogy.
 
 
@article{dhar20071,
 
  title={The Impact of Intellectual Property Rights in the Plant and Seed Industry},
 
  author={Dhar, T. and Foltz, J.},
 
  journal={Agricultural Biotechnolgy and Intellectual Property Protection: Seeds of Change},
 
  pages={161},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={CABI},
 
  filename={Dhar Foltz (2007) - The Impact Of Intellectual Property Rights In The Plant And Seed Industry.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory with some empirics: Plant/Seed Industry
 
 
UBC Marketing Prof...
 
 
A number of observers of patenting, particularly in the biological sciences, have
 
suggested that patenting rules and overlapping claims have generated a "patent thicket"
 
8
 
that has impeded innovation and made the R&D process more costly (Rai, 2001; Rai,
 
1999). Rai (2001) for example, argues that broad patents especially on upstream platform
 
technologies represent a threat to competition and the cumulative process of innovation in
 
the biopharmaceutical industry
 
 
Our work makes a start both theoretically and empirically in recognizing the
 
important strategic role of revelation loss in firm strategies of choice of intellectual
 
property rights or trade secrets.
 
 
@article{d2009pools,
 
  title={Pools, thickets and open source nanotechnology},
 
  author={D'Silva, J.},
 
  journal={European intellectual property review},
 
  volume={31},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={300--306},
 
  year={2009},
 
  filename={DSilva (2009) - Pools Thickets And Open Source Nanotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion: Nanotech
 
 
When multiple organisations each own
 
individual patents that are collectively necessary for a particular technology,
 
their competing intellectual property rights form a "patent thicket".
 
 
@article{eisenmann2008managing,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Managing Proprietary and Shared Platforms},
 
  author = {Eisenmann, Thomas R.},
 
  journal = {California Management Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {50},
 
  number = {4},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Summer 2008},
 
  pages = {pp. 31-53},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/41166455},
 
  ISSN = {00081256},
 
  abstract = {In a platform-mediated network, users rely on a common platform (provided by one or more intermediaries) that encompasses infrastructure and rules required by users to transact with each other. A fundamental design decision for firms that aspire to develop platform-mediated networks is whether to preserve proprietary control or share their platform with rivals. A proprietary platform has a single provider that solely controls its technology (for example, Federal Express, Apple Macintosh, or Google). With a shared platform such as Visa, DVD, or Linux, multiple firms collaborate in developing the platform's technology and then compete in offering users different but compatible versions of the platform. This article examines factors that favor proprietary versus shared models when designing platforms and then explains how management challenges differ for proprietary and shared platform providers when mobilizing new networks.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2008},
 
  publisher = {University of California Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2008 University of California Press},
 
  filename={Eisenmann (2008) - Managing Proprietary And Shared Platforms.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt: Discussion: Platforms (TV adds)
 
 
A second type of IP-based claim can occur when shared platforms rely on many different patented technologies, each of which has no obvious substitute. Firms may find themselves in a patent "thicket," in which several parties are able to derail a shared platform by threatening to withhold necessary contribu- tions.12 Each firm can issue an ultimatum, demanding a large share of the plat- form's added value
 
 
@article{eisenstein2010up,
 
  title={Up for grabs},
 
  author={Eisenstein, M.},
 
  journal={Nature Biotechnology},
 
  volume={28},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={544--546},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Nature Publishing Group},
 
  filename={Eisenstein (2010) - Up For Grabs.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: Discussion: Stem Cells
 
 
As recently as three months ago, it still all seemed
 
so simple. Shinya Yamanaka, whose team at
 
the University of Kyoto in Japan is generally
 
acknowledged by the research community as the
 
first to successfully reprogram differentiated cells
 
into iPS cells1, was also the sole patent holder for
 
the technology. But as with any other patent land
 
grab, iPS cell intellectual property (IP) is beginning
 
to look less and less like a one-horse race.
 
Two other recently issued patents in the
 
United States and United Kingdom (Table 1),
 
each awarded to a different inventor with a
 
potentially strong claim to priority, now stand
 
alongside Yamanaka’s patent, which was exclusively
 
issued in Japan. With this newly tangled IP
 
landscape, questions are arising about the possible
 
emergence of a patent thicket.
 
 
@misc{entezarkheir2010patent,
 
  title={Patent Thickets and Market Value: An Empirical Analysis},
 
  author={Entezarkheir, M.},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Entezarkheir (2010) - Patent Thickets And Market Value An Empirical Analysis.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: CORE PAPER
 
 
In this paper, I study how the fragmentation of the ownership of complementary patents
 
impacts the market value of the firm. This fragmentation builds a patent thicket, which
 
contains a set of overlapping patents.3 The patent thicket requires obtaining permission
 
from several right holders to commercialize a product. Firms that face a fragmented
 
technology market have to pay higher transaction costs and royalty payments to license
 
external patents, because they are confronted with larger number of entities in the thicket.
 
They are more prone to opportunistic behaviour by external entities, since the likelihood
 
of infringing other firms’ patents is high. They are also more exposed to the risk of being
 
litigated against by other patent holders. Finally, they incur higher costs in finding out
 
whether the technologies they use have been patented by other firms.
 
 
@article{evans2004software,
 
  title={Software patents and open source: the battle over intellectual property rights},
 
  author={Evans, D.S. and Layne-Farrar, A.},
 
  journal={Va. JL \& Tech.},
 
  volume={9},
 
  pages={10--13},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Virginia Journal of Law and Technology Virginia Journal of Law and Technology},
 
  filename={Evans LayneFarrar (2004) - Software Patents And Open Source.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Discussion: Sofware CORE PAPER
 
 
The theoretical economics literature argues that when innovations are sequential and cumulative, patents may impose more than the typical exclusion-period costs.113 For instance, a patent for an invention early in the innovative process could impose a toll on each sequential innovation that relies on it. Subsequent inventors, therefore, face higher transaction costs––they must pay licensing fees before they can further refine a technology. As the tolls build during the technology’s development path, later research could be discouraged altogether. Alluding to the famous argument for property rights, over-patenting has been dubbed the “tragedy of the anticommons,” as too many people with exclusionary rights can cause underutilization of resources.114 Shapiro uses another metaphor: the patent thicket
 
 
the truth resides in one strain of the theoretical literature arguing against patents. Similarly, while the law and economics literature has established that patent thickets are possible, what little empirical evidence is available on this point indicates that they are not inevitable. Means of working around the exclusionary effects of patents––such as patent pools and cross-licensing––are available to the software industry.
 
 
@article{farrell2009intellectual,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Intellectual Property as a Bargaining Environment},
 
  author = {Farrell, Joseph},
 
  journal = {Innovation Policy and the Economy},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {9},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {2009},
 
  pages = {pp. 39-53},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/592420},
 
  ISSN = {15313468},
 
  abstract = {Executive Summary Intellectual property policy relies on bargaining in the shadow of exclusivity. But bargaining is generically less than fully efficient, and the bargaining that would be needed to reach efficient arrangements in the shadow of exclusivity may be especially difficult in certain ways. I explore these issues and illustrate with brief discussions of patent pools and standards organizations, among others.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2009},
 
  publisher = {The University of Chicago Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2009 The National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Farrell (2009) - Intellectual Property As A Bargaining Environment.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Discussion: Bargaining in IP CORE and DOWN paper
 
 
One common and intuitively difficult information problem arises
 
when a producer does not know with whom it must negotiate concerning
 
patents. One might call this a “potential-patent thicket,” as distinct
 
from the “actual-patent thicket” that can create multiple-marginalization
 
problems when many patents are known to be infringed by a product.
 
 
@article{federal2003promote,
 
  title={To promote innovation: The proper balance of competition and patent law and policy},
 
  author={Federal Trade Commission},
 
  journal={Washington, DC},
 
  year={2003},
 
  filename={FTC (2003) - To Promote Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Key FTC report
 
 
This tends to create
 
a “patent thicket” – that is, a “dense web of
 
overlapping intellectual property rights that
 
a company must hack its way through in
 
order to actually commercialize new
 
technology.
 
 
Questionable patents contribute to
 
the patent thicket. In the context of a patent
 
thicket, questionable patents can introduce
 
new kinds of licensing difficulties, such as
 
royalties stacked one on top of another, and
 
can increase uncertainty about the patent
 
landscape, thus complicating business
 
planning. Questionable patents in patent
 
thickets can frustrate competition by current
 
manufacturers as well as potential entrants.
 
Because a manufacturer needs a license to
 
all of the patents that cover its product, firms
 
can use questionable patents to extract high
 
royalties or to threaten litigation
 
 
@article{federal2011evolving,
 
  title={The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning patent notice and remedies with competition.”},
 
  author={Federal Trade Commission},
 
  journal={March, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/03/110307patentreport.pdf},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={FTC (2011) - The Evolving IP Marketplace.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Key FTC report
 
 
See above. We should compare the two reports!
 
 
@article{feldman2004open,
 
  title={The Open Source Biotechnology Movement: Is It Patent Misuse?},
 
  author={Feldman, R.},
 
  journal={Minnesota Journal of Law, Science \& Technology},
 
  volume={6},
 
  year={2004},
 
  filename={Feldman (2004) - The Open Source Biotechnology Movement Is It Patent Misuse.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory/Discussion: Biotech, open source
 
 
Scholars have used the term “patent thicket” to describe the problem of multiple
 
overlapping rights that can hamper innovation by creating transaction barriers.20 Most
 
scholars and those reporting from the field agree that large numbers of rights hamper
 
research and innovation, particularly in the biotech field.21 One scholar, however, has
 
challenged the notion.22 John Walsh argues that firms simply work around the problem
 
of multiple rights for example, by moving offshore beyond the reach of the patent rights,
 
inventing around the rights, and using public research tools.23 In particular, Walsh argues
 
that academic researchers routinely ignore rights structures and that patent holders
 
passively acquiesce.
 
 
@article{feldman2008open,
 
  title={Open Source, Open Access, Open Transfer: Market Approaches to Research Bottlenecks},
 
  author={Feldman, R. and Nelson, K.},
 
  year={2008},
 
  filename={Feldman Nelson (2008) - Open Source Open Access Open Transfer.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory: Academic research tools
 
 
On the patent front, a key debate concerns the existence, or non-existence, of
 
bottlenecks such as patent thickets and the extent to which any patent thickets may be
 
interfering with research. For decades, scholars warned that problems related to the over
 
proliferation of patent rights would interfere with innovation.1 In theory, multiple
 
overlapping patent rights can hamper innovation by creating high transactions costs as
 
researchers try to navigate the tangle of existing rights. These costs can discourage
 
investment in research or distort the paths that researchers take due to the difficulty of
 
identifying and negotiating all of the underlying rights necessary to begin researching.
 
This leads to inefficiencies and underutilization of intellectual resources. Across the
 
years, patent mavens traded stories of research deterred or research deferred due to patent
 
thickets.2 Innovation costs also may rise as rational enterprises factor in the risk that their
 
inventions will be plagued by suits from patent holders who emerge from the shadows of
 
the patent thicket to claim a share as soon as the invention is successful.3
 
 
@article{fischer2011patent,
 
  title={Patent Trolls on Markets for Technology-An Empirical Analysis of Trolls' Patent Acquisitions},
 
  author={Fischer, T. and Henkel, J.},
 
  journal={Available at SSRN 1523102},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={Fischer Henkel (2011) - Patent Trolls On Markets For Technology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Trolls - which patents they buy
 
 
The second patent characteristic patent trolls should favor is a high cost of substituting
 
the underlying invention in products. This substitution cost increases with the difficulty of
 
inventing around the patent, which in turn is high if the patent density and complexity of the
 
relevant technology field is high. This means that many patents exist that have a high degree
 
of overlap between them and with the patent under consideration, so that finding a gap for a
 
non-patented substitutive technology is difficult. In other words, the focal patent is part of a
 
patent thicket (Shapiro, 2001).
 
 
@article{galasso2007broad,
 
  title={Broad cross-license agreements and persuasive patent litigation: theory and evidence from the semiconductor industry},
 
  author={Galasso, A.},
 
  journal={LSE STICERD Research Paper No. EI45},
 
  year={2007},
 
  filename={Galasso (2007) - Broad Cross License Agreements And Persuasive Patent Litigation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory and empirics: Determining cross-license agreements
 
 
To uncover the incentives behind these contracts, I have developed a model of
 
bargaining with learning in which firms litigate over their patent disputes if they do
 
not agree upon a cross-license. The model predicts that the incentive to litigate decreases
 
with firm investment in specific technology. More precisely, I have shown that
 
whereas firms with low asset specificity prefer not to sign a cross-license agreement,
 
firms with high sunk costs are better off cross-licensing their intellectual property. In
 
addition, the model predicts that firms with intermediate levels of sunk costs will engage
 
in inefficient “persuasive” litigation aimed at obtaining a better deal in a broad
 
cross-license contract.
 
I have tested the predictions of the model using a novel dataset merging data
 
on cross-license agreements, patent litigation and financial variables for firms in the
 
semiconductor industry.
 
 
renders it difficult to commercialize a new technology. In some industries the number
 
of intellectual property rights a firm requires to produce a new product is so large,
 
and their ownership is so dispersed, that it is quite easy to unintentionally infringe
 
on a patent. In this environment there is, therefore, a hold-up problem: when the
 
manufacturer starts selling its product a patentee might show up threatening to shut
 
production down unless it is paid high royalties.
 
 
@article{galasso2008patent,
 
  title={Patent Thickets and the Market for Innovation: Evidence from Settlement of Patent Disputes},
 
  author={Galasso, A. and Schankerman, M.},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP6946},
 
  filename={Galasso Schankerman (2008) - Patent Thickets And The Market For Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Fragmentation leads to quicker settlement (CORE PAPER)
 
 
are the fragmentation of patent rights (often
 
referred to as ‘patent thickets’)
 
 
In this paper we investigate how the fragmentation of patent rights and the introduction
 
2
 
in 1982 of the Court of Appeal for the Federal Circuit (CAFC) affected the length of (costly)
 
patent infringement disputes. We develop a model that focuses on how the uncertainty of
 
the enforcement regime and ‘upstream’ fragmentation affect ‘downstream’ bargaining behavior
 
during patent litigation. Our model extends the settlement negotiation game of Bebchuk (1984)
 
and Spier (1992) by considering features of patent ownership fragmentation similar to those
 
described in Lerner and Tirole (2004). The model shows that settlement agreements will be
 
reached more quickly when the patent rights needed by the infringer are more fragmented
 
(ownership is more dispersed) and in the more ‘certain’ enforcement regime associated with
 
CAFC.
 
 
@article{galasso2010patent,
 
  title={Patent thickets, courts, and the market for innovation},
 
  author={Galasso, A. and Schankerman, M.},
 
  journal={The RAND journal of economics},
 
  volume={41},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={472--503},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Galasso Schankerman (2010) - Patent Thickets Courts And The Market For Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory and Empirical: Fragmentation leads to quicker settlement (CORE PAPER)
 
 
Seems like an improved version of above with a model? READ IT PROPERLY!
 
 
@article{gallini2011private,
 
  title={Private agreements for coordinating patent rights: the case of patent pools},
 
  author={Gallini, N.},
 
  journal={Economia e Politica Industriale},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={FrancoAngeli Editore},
 
  filename={Gallini (2011) - Private Agreements For Coordinating Patent Rights.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Patent Pools
 
 
In synthesizing the ideas advanced in the economic literature, this paper
 
explores whether these antitrust concerns apply to pools with complementary patents and, if they do, the
 
implications for competition policy to constrain them. Special attention is given to the application of the U.S.
 
Department of Justice-Federal Trade Commission Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995) and its
 
companion Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (2007)
 
to recent patent pool cases.
 
 
A patent thicket arises when there are overlapping patent rights that must be identified and licensed in order for an
 
innovator to bring a new product or technology to market
 
 
@article{gallini2002economics,
 
  title={The economics of patents: Lessons from recent US patent reform},
 
  author={Gallini, N.T.},
 
  journal={Journal of Economic Perspectives},
 
  pages={131--154},
 
  year={2002},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Gallini (2002) - The Economics Of Patents Lessons From Recent Us Patent Reform.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Policy: Patent Policy basics and reform
 
 
Doesn't mention thickets explicitly.
 
 
Good material for the underpinnings...
 
 
@incollection{gallini2002intellectual,
 
  title={Intellectual property: when is it the best incentive system?},
 
  author={Gallini, N. and Scotchmer, S.},
 
  booktitle={Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 2},
 
  pages={51--78},
 
  year={2002},
 
  publisher={MIT Press},
 
  filename={Gallini Scotchmer (2002) - Intellectual Property When Is It The Best Incentive System.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Policy: Best IP incentive system
 
 
Doesn't mention thickets explicitly.
 
 
Good material for the underpinnings...
 
 
A recurring theme, especially evident in these
 
contexts, is that despite the efficiencies that contracting can ensure, contracting may
 
also facilitate anti-competitive behavior. See Hall and Ham (1999), Shapiro (2000),
 
Denicolò (2000). To understand whether the property system is too strong, too
 
weak, or necessary at all requires us to understand the incentives for contracting,
 
and its potential anticompetitive consequences.
 
 
@article{ganslandt2009intellectual,
 
  title={Intellectual property rights and competition policy},
 
  author={Ganslandt, M.},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Emerald Group Publishing Limited},
 
  filename={Ganslandt (2009) - Intellectual Property Rights And Competition Policy.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Patent and Antitrust
 
 
Intellectual property rights and competition policy are intimately related. In this paper I
 
survey the economic literature analyzing the interaction between intellectual property law
 
and competition law and how the boundary between these two policies is drawn in
 
practice.
 
 
In some industries, particularly biotechnology and information technologies, it is
 
common that a new entrant, in order to engage in research or production, must obtain a
 
large number of licenses from existing and previous innovators and producers. This
 
problem raises the cost of product commercialization and may create substantial entry
 
barriers for new firms. For example, Bessen and Meurer (2006) point to the fact that the
 
large number of patents facing a typical innovator makes careful assessment of avenues
 
open for competition burdensome and costly.
 
 
@article{gaule2006towards,
 
  title={Towards Patent Pools in Biotechnology?},
 
  author={Gaul{\'e}, P.},
 
  journal={Innovation Strategy Today},
 
  volume={2},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={123--143},
 
  year={2006},
 
  filename={Gaule (2006) - Towards Patent Pools In Biotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt/Law: Discussion (v. small): Biotech
 
 
The IP rights situation described above was arguably a classical case of a patent thicket with fragmented IP rights
 
and uncertainty about technology ownership. The option of a patent pool for this technology was raised (Fedson 04), but instead
 
the situation was resolved by one patent owner acquiring exclusive licenses from the other ones.
 
 
@article{george2006hiding,
 
  title={What Is Hiding in the Bushes-Ebay's Effect on Holdout Behavior in Patent Thickets},
 
  author={George, G.D.},
 
  journal={Mich. Telecomm. \& Tech. L. Rev.},
 
  volume={13},
 
  pages={557},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={George (2006) - What Is Hiding In The Bushes Ebays Effect On Holdout Behavior In Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion: CORE PAPER
 
 
A patent thicket exists where there are
 
numerous different firms holding patents that are legally and technologically
 
distinct, but overlap to cover a much smaller number of actual or
 
potential commercial products.2 For example, over five thousand patents
 
have now been granted in the area of nanotechnology despite the fact that
 
no nanotech products have yet been commercialized.3
 
 
@article{geradin2007royalty,
 
  title={Royalty stacking in high tech industries: separating myth from reality},
 
  author={Geradin, D. and Layne-Farrar, A. and Padilla Blanco, A.},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP6091},
 
  filename={Geradin (2007) - Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Review: CORE Paper
 
 
Shaprio def. But has lit review and history.
 
 
@article{geradin2008complements,
 
  title={The complements problem within standard setting: assessing the evidence on royalty stacking},
 
  author={Geradin, D. and Layne-Farrar, A. and Padilla Blanco, A.},
 
  journal={Boston University Journal of Science and Technology Law, Vol. 14, No. 2, 2008},
 
  year={2008},
 
  filename={Geradin LayneFarrar PadillaBlanco (2008) - The Complements Problem Within Standard Setting.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Review: CORE PAPER (Might be same as above)
 
 
@article{geroski2005intellectual,
 
  title={Intellectual Property Rights, Competition Policy and Innovation: Is There a Problem?},
 
  author={Geroski, P.A.},
 
  journal={SCRIPT ed},
 
  volume={2},
 
  year={2005},
 
  filename={Geroski (2005) - Intellectual Property Rights Competition Policy And Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Competition vs. patents
 
 
The second problem arises with complex innovations. When a new innovation draws
 
on several different areas of technology, then the innovator will need to undertake a
 
series of bilateral negotiations with existing intellectual property rights holders if
 
his/her innovation is to see the light of day. This, in turn, means that any individual
 
antecedent patent holder has the ability to hold up the new innovation, possibly using
 
this bargaining power to extract most of the returns that it promises to produce for its
 
creator. These “patent thickets”, as they are sometimes called, basically inflate the
 
(2005) 2:4 SCRIPT-ed
 
425
 
transactions costs of developing a new innovation, and are, therefore, likely to inhibit
 
the rate of development of new ideas or the good and services that come from them.
 
 
I started this paper with a question - is the system of intellectual property rights, with
 
which we are all familiar, the best way to stimulate innovation? The gist of what I
 
have had to say is that the answer is “maybe”. In a sense, this is not a surprising
 
conclusion: it is just too hard to be sure what the best policy is in almost every setting
 
in which this question comes up. At a more sensible level, however, “maybe” is an
 
answer pregnant with possibilities. Most of these arise from two different types of
 
observations: first, that intellectual property rights systems can inhibit innovation, or
 
at least distort it in particular directions; and second, that competition and innovation
 
are not inimical.
 
For me, as a competition policy practitioner, the argument that competition stimulates
 
innovation is an important one, for it suggests that competition policy is not
 
necessarily in conflict with the use of intellectual property rights to stimulate
 
innovation. At a practical level, this argument seems to me to have two implications.
 
First, it seems clear that one ought to regard restrictive licensing practices as just what
 
they are: namely, restrictive practices. In this, as in many other areas of anti-trust, the
 
rule of reason ought to apply. That is, such practices should be evaluated in the
 
context of the benefits which they might – or might not – bring to consumers, in both
 
the short and also the long run. Second, anything that substantially lessens, or
 
adversely affects, competition in a particular market is, or should at least potentially
 
be regarded as, a threat to innovation. And, finally, the need to stimulate innovation is
 
the one thing that both competition policy and intellectual property rights have in
 
common.
 
 
@article{gilbert2004antitrust,
 
  title={Antitrust for patent pools: A century of policy evolution},
 
  author={Gilbert, R.J.},
 
  journal={Stanford Technology Law Review},
 
  volume={2004},
 
  year={2004},
 
  filename={Gilbert (2004) - Antitrust For Patent Pools A Century Of Policy Evolution.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: History of Anti-trust and patent pools
 
 
The court ruled that the agreement to license
 
present and future patents and to share know-how contributed to a patent thicket that created a
 
barrier to new entry and allowed DuPont and National Lead to control the domestic industry for
 
titanium dioxide products.
 
 
@article{gilbert2010ties,
 
  title={Ties That Bind: Policies to Promote (Good) Patent Pools},
 
  author={Gilbert, R.J.},
 
  journal={Antitrust Law Journal},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Gilbert (2010) - Ties That Bind Policies To Promote Good Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion: Patent Pools as a solution to thickets - anti-trust's take on this...
 
 
A “patent thicket,” in which many independent patent holders have
 
rights that cover a technology, is one example of the anticommons.5 A
 
patent thicket exists when rights to many patents from different patentees
 
are necessary to lawfully make or sell a product (overlapping
 
rights).6 Patent thickets are common to many high-technology industries
 
in which the manufacture, use, or sale of a device or process may
 
require rights to hundreds of patents.7 Overlapping patent rights raise
 
numerous potential economic problems. Transaction costs of licensing
 
can be high because licensees must identify, search out, and negotiate
 
with numerous separate licensors. Litigation risks can be high because
 
an incomplete portfolio of patent licenses can expose a firm to potentially
 
large infringement damages. Royalties can be high if each of many
 
independent licensors of complementary patents attempts to obtain a
 
large share of the economic value of products that may infringe its patent.
 
For these reasons a patent thicket can raise prices and discourage
 
innovation relative to a situation with fewer patents or with coordinated
 
licensing of the overlapping patent rights.8
 
 
@article{gilbert1982preemptive,
 
  title={Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly},
 
  author={Gilbert, R.J. and Newbery, D.M.G.},
 
  journal={The American Economic Review},
 
  pages={514--526},
 
  year={1982},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Gilbert Newbery (1982) - Preemptive Patenting And The Persistence Of Monopoly.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Entry deterence (monopoly)
 
 
This paper takes a different tack
 
and inquires whether institutions such as the
 
patent system create opportunities for firms
 
with monopoly power to maintain their monopoly
 
power. The results apply to other
 
situations such as brand identification, spatial
 
location, and capacity expansion, which
 
share the characteristic that early, or preemptive,
 
actions may lower the returns to
 
potential competitors.
 
Preemptive invention is not without topical
 
interest. In a recent antitrust case-the
 
longest jury trial on record in the federal
 
courts-the SCM Corporation sought more
 
than $500 million in damages on its claim
 
that the Xerox Corporation, among other
 
alleged anticompetitiveb ehavior,h ad maintained
 
a "patent thicket" where some inventions
 
were used while others were neither
 
used nor licensed to others
 
 
 
@article{goozner2006innovation,
 
  title={Innovation in biomedicine: can stem cell research lead the way to affordability?},
 
  author={Goozner, M.},
 
  journal={PLoS medicine},
 
  volume={3},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={e126},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Public Library of Science},
 
  filename={Goozner (2006) - Innovation In Biomedicine.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: Policy: Stem Cell
 
 
The current innovation
 
system encourages researchers to
 
patent and commercialize discoveries
 
that in an earlier era were considered
 
basic science insights. This has led to
 
an active market in the building blocks
 
of further research, which can be
 
anything from a genetic sequence or a
 
cell receptor to the reagents needed to
 
culture cells. This proliferation of basic
 
science patents has raised the bar—
 
what economists call transaction costs—
 
for other researchers who want access
 
to those research tools. While many
 
researchers, especially in academia,
 
fi nd ways around patent restrictions,
 
and many companies have no trouble
 
executing license agreements, there
 
are cases where “patent thickets” have
 
discouraged other researchers from
 
pursuing similar or subsequent lines of
 
inquiry [5].
 
 
@article{grindley1997licensing,
 
  title={Licensing and Cross-Licensing in Semiconductors and Electronics},
 
  author={Grindley, P.C. and Teece, D.J.},
 
  journal={California Management Review},
 
  volume={39},
 
  number={2},
 
  year={1997},
 
  filename={Grindley Teece (1997) - Licensing And Cross Licensing In Semiconductors And Electronics.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt: Cross-licensing, semiconductors
 
 
No mention of thickets. But old (seminal) paper.
 
  
 
  @article{gugler2007market,
 
  @article{gugler2007market,
Line 1,635: Line 12:
 
   author = {Gugler, Klaus and Siebert, Ralph},
 
   author = {Gugler, Klaus and Siebert, Ralph},
 
   journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
 
   journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
 
   volume = {89},
 
   volume = {89},
 
   number = {4},
 
   number = {4},
Line 1,656: Line 32:
 
Incre- mental process innovations occur more frequently in the memory segment, creating a higher density of the patent thicket. This fact is in line with the patent thicket literature
 
Incre- mental process innovations occur more frequently in the memory segment, creating a higher density of the patent thicket. This fact is in line with the patent thicket literature
 
see, for example, Hall and Ziedonis (2001) and Shapiro (2001).1
 
see, for example, Hall and Ziedonis (2001) and Shapiro (2001).1
 
@article{hall2005note,
 
  title={A note on the bias in Herfindahl-type measures based on count data},
 
  author={Hall, B.H.},
 
  journal={Revue D' Economie Industrielle, Paris Editions, Techniques Et Economiques},
 
  volume={110},
 
  pages={149},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={Citeseer},
 
  filename={Hall (2005) - A Note On The Bias In Herfindahl Type Measures Based On Count Data.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Econometrics: CORE PAPER!
 
 
@article{hall2005exploring,
 
  title={Exploring the patent explosion},
 
  author={Hall, B.},
 
  journal={Essays in Honor of Edwin Mansfield},
 
  pages={195--208},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={Springer},
 
  filename={Hall (2005) - Exploring The Patent Explosion.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patents
 
 
No mention of thickets in 2005 paper!
 
 
I am able to confirm that after the mid-1980s, patents held by
 
entrants to the publicly traded sector are indeed more highly valued than those
 
held by incumbents. An industry decomposition of this effect shows that it is
 
concentrated in what Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh (2001) label complex product
 
industries, which are industries where a single products can contain intellectual
 
property covered by thousands of patents held by hundreds of patentholders. In
 
such industries, patent portfolios often serve the defensive function of
 
facilitating cross-licensing negotiations, rather than the traditional role of
 
excluding competitors and securing the ownership of particular inventions.
 
Although patent yield per se is not valued for incumbents in any of the
 
industries, I show that in complex product industries there has been a strong
 
positive shift in valuation for entrants as we enter the pro-patent era.
 
 
@article{hall2007patents,
 
  title={Patents and patent policy},
 
  author={Hall, B.H.},
 
  journal={Oxford Review of Economic Policy},
 
  volume={23},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={568--587},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Oxford Univ Press},
 
  filename={Hall (2007) - Patents And Patent Policy.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patents
 
 
Barely mentions thickets, but sets the stage well.
 
 
During the U.S. Federal Trade Commission/Department of Justice hearings on the patent system
 
and antitrust policy in 2002, a number of industry representatives expressed concerns about the
 
difficulty of negotiating the patent thicket in their area and the risk of being “held-up” ex post by
 
a patent on a technology that was only a small component of their product. This complaint was
 
heard largely from those in the complex product industries (the ICT sector), such as Robert Barr,
 
then Vice-President for Intellectual Property and Worldwide Patent Counsel at Cisco
 
Corporation. He described two types of problems faced by firms in the sector: the first being the
 
large stockpiling of patents necessary as a defensive measure against others in the industry and
 
the second being the threat posed by small entities that have nothing at risk themselves and may
 
not even be producers.
 
 
The first of the problems Barr describes is clearly a case of mutually assured destruction that
 
leaves the firms in question no better (and no worse) off than if they were not accumulating
 
massive numbers of patents for defensive purposes, and yet at the same time is a very costly
 
strategy.
 
 
@article{hall2012study,
 
  title={A Study of Patent Thickets},
 
  author={Hall, B.H. and Helmers, C. and von Graevenitz, G. and Rosazza-Bondibene, C.},
 
  journal={Draft Report to the UK IPO},
 
  pages={1--66},
 
  year={2012},
 
  filename={Hall (2012) - A Study Of Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patent Thickets!: CORE PAPER
 
 
A patent thicket is “a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology” (Shapiro, 2000). Patent thickets consist of patents that protect components of a modular and complex technology. Here modular means that different sets of components can be assembled to yield a variety of technological products. Complex means that products consist of tens or hundreds of such modular components. Each component may end up being used in several products. Often there are partial or complete overlaps in the functionality of components and then the patents protecting the components may also overlap. If overlapping patents belong to different firms, then a patent thicket exists.
 
 
@article{hall2001patent,
 
  title={The patent paradox revisited: an empirical study of patenting in the US semiconductor industry, 1979-1995},
 
  author={Hall, B.H. and Ziedonis, R.H.},
 
  journal={RAND Journal of Economics},
 
  pages={101--128},
 
  year={2001},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Hall Ziedonis (2001) - The Patent Paradox Revisited.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Semiconductors: CORE PAPER
 
 
@article{hargreaves2011digital,
 
  title={Digital opportunity: a review of intellectual property and growth: an independent report},
 
  author={Hargreaves, I.},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Intellectual Property Office},
 
  filename={Hargreaves (2011) - Digital Opportunity.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: CORE PAPER
 
 
This patenting boom is
 
leading to problems of patent office backlogs and the emergence of so called “patent thickets”, which
 
obstruct entry to some markets and so impede innovation.
 
6. Patent thickets and other obstructions to innovation. In order to limit the effects of these
 
barriers to innovation, the Government should:
 
• take a leading role in promoting international efforts to cut backlogs and manage the boom in
 
patent applications by further extending “work sharing” with patent offices in other countries;
 
• work to ensure patents are not extended into sectors, such as non-technical computer
 
programs and business methods, which they do not currently cover, without clear evidence of
 
benefit;
 
• investigate ways of limiting adverse consequences of patent thickets, including by working
 
with international partners to establish a patent fee structure set by reference to innovation
 
and growth goals rather than solely by reference to patent office running costs. The structure
 
of patent renewal fees might be adjusted to encourage patentees to assess more carefully the
 
value of maintaining lower value patents, so reducing the density of patent thickets.
 
 
This finding may be due to the existence of patent thickets – meaning “an overlapping set of patent rights” which require innovators to reach licensing deals for multiple patents from multiple sources.12 These thickets appear to enable patent holders to exclude new and innovative firms from entering the market, thereby inhibiting growth. In these high technology and information intensive sectors we need to ensure that the IP system acts as a net incentive to innovation and growth.
 
 
@article{harhoff2008incidence,
 
  title={Incidence and Growth of Patent Thickets-The Impact of Technological Opportunities and Complexity},
 
  author={Harhoff, D. and Von Graevenitz, G. and Wagner, S.},
 
  journal={CEPR Discussion Papers},
 
  volume={6900},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Papers},
 
  filename={Harhoff (2008) - Incidence And Growth Of Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patent thickets: 88-02, 30 industries, EPO data CORE PAPER
 
 
fragmentation index has predominantly been studied in complex industries (Ziedonis, 2004,
 
Schankerman and Noel, 2006) where increasing fragmentation raises firms’ patent applications.
 
This is attributed to firms’ efforts to reduce potential hold-up by opportunistic patentees
 
owning critical or blocking patent rights – a situation which is associated with the existence of
 
patent thickets. This index does not measure hold-up potential as precisely as the complexity
 
measure we discuss above.
 
 
@article{harhoff2012conflict,
 
  title={Conflict Resolution, Public Goods and Patent Thickets},
 
  author={Harhoff, D. and Von Graevenitz, G. and Wagner, S.},
 
  journal={Public Goods and Patent Thickets (April 15, 2012)},
 
  year={2012},
 
  filename={Harhoff VonGraevenitz Wagner (2012) - Conflict Resolution Public Goods And Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: EPO data CORE PAPER
 
 
Moreover, the presence of patent thickets, i.e., fields with a high number of patents that have
 
similar or overlapping claims
 
 
@article{hegde2009pioneering,
 
  title={Pioneering Inventors or Thicket Builders: Which US Firms Use Continuations in Patenting?},
 
  author={Hegde, D. and Mowery, D.C. and Graham, S.J.H.},
 
  journal={Management Science},
 
  volume={55},
 
  number={7},
 
  pages={1214--1226},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={INFORMS},
 
  filename={Hegde Mowery Graham (2009) - Pioneering Inventors Or Thicket Builders.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patent Continuations: CORE PAPER (just)
 
These lower-quality patents can be valuable to patentholders
 
seeking to accumulate a thicket of patents
 
for “defensive” purposes and/or to improve their bargaining
 
position in patent cross-licensing negotiations
 
(Shapiro 2001). Additionally, according to Lemley and
 
Moore (2004), inventors may use the continuations
 
procedure to increase uncertainty for rivals’ research
 
and development (R&D) investment decisions, or to
 
acquire so-called “submarine patents.”1�2
 
 
A high proportion of backward self-cites is another potential correlate
 
of patenting strategies that accumulate “thickets” of patents
 
that overlap and cite one another. We found that patents owned by
 
Compustat firms issuing from post-1995 CAPs contained a significantly
 
higher proportion of backward self-citations than any other
 
group of patents, whereas CAPs prior to 1995 cited their own
 
patents less frequently than patents issuing from any other type of
 
continuation. This provides additional evidence on the increased
 
use of CAPs in post-1995 strategies that involve building thickets
 
of patents.
 
 
@article{heller1998thetragedy,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets},
 
  author = {Heller, Michael A.},
 
  journal = {Harvard Law Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {111},
 
  number = {3},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Jan., 1998},
 
  pages = {pp. 621-688},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/1342203},
 
  ISSN = {0017811X},
 
  abstract = {Why are many storefronts in Moscow empty, while street kiosks in front are full of goods? In this Article, Professor Heller develops a theory of anticommons property to help explain the puzzle of empty storefronts and full kiosks. Anticommons property can be understood as the mirror image of commons property. By definition, in a commons, multiple owners are each endowed with the privilege to use a given resource, and no one has the right to exclude another. When too many owners hold such privileges of use, the resource is prone to overuse - a tragedy of the commons. Depleted fisheries and overgrazed fields are canonical examples of this familiar tragedy. In an anticommons, according to this Article, multiple owners are each endowed with the right to exclude others from a scarce resource, and no one has an effective privilege of use. When too many owners hold such rights of exclusion, the resource is prone to underuse - a tragedy of the anticommons. Empty Moscow storefronts are a canonical example of the tragedy of underuse. Anticommons property may appear whenever governments define new property rights in both post-socialist and developed market economies. Once an anticommons emerges, collecting rights into usable private property bundles can be brutal and slow. The difficulties of overcoming a tragedy of the anticommons suggest that policymakers should pay more attention to the content of property bundles, rather than focusing just on the clairty of rights.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {1998},
 
  publisher = {The Harvard Law Review Association},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 1998 The Harvard Law Review Association},
 
  filename={Heller (1998) - The Tragedy Of The Anticommons.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: SEMINAL DOWN (FOUNDATION) ARTICLE.
 
 
In an anticommons,
 
according to this Article, multiple owners are each endowed with the right to exclude
 
others from a scarce resource, and no one has an effective privilege of use. When too many
 
owners hold such rights of exclusion, the resource is prone to underuse - a tragedy of the
 
anticommons.
 
 
In the United States, vivid examples appear at the frontiers of
 
Native American law and intellectual property protection.20
 
 
See infra section IV.D (discussing an anticommons in Native American allotted lands). In a
 
forthcoming article, Rebecca Eisenberg and the author of this Article show how the recent proliferation
 
of patent rights in basic biomedical research may lead paradoxically to fewer useful pharmaceutical
 
products and procedures in the United States. A tragedy of the anticommons may be
 
the unintended consequence of privatizing basic biomedical research.
 
 
 
@article{heller1998can,
 
  title={Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research},
 
  author={Heller, M.A. and Eisenberg, R.S.},
 
  journal={Science},
 
  volume={280},
 
  number={5364},
 
  pages={698--701},
 
  year={1998},
 
  publisher={American Association for the Advancement of Science},
 
  filename={Heller Eisenberg (1998) - Can Patents Deter Innovation The Anticommons In Biomedical Research.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: CORE PAPER!!!
 
 
Never uses the term thicket. Foundational application of anti-commons to biotech patents.
 
 
In theory, in a world of costless
 
transactions, people could always avoid
 
commons or anticommons tragedies by
 
trading their rights (10). In practice, however,
 
avoiding tragedy requires overcoming
 
transaction costs, strategic behaviors, and
 
cognitive biases of participants (11), with
 
success more likely within close-knit communities
 
than among hostile strangers (12–
 
14). Once an anticommons emerges, collecting
 
rights into usable private property is
 
often brutal and slow (15).
 
 
@article{hemphill2003preemptive,
 
  title={Preemptive patenting, human genomics, and the US biotechnology sector: balancing intellectual property rights with societal welfare},
 
  author={Hemphill, T.A.},
 
  journal={Technology in Society},
 
  volume={25},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={337--349},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Hemphill (2003) - Preemptive Patenting Human Genomics And The Us Biotechnology Sector.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy (academic): Biotech: human genomics
 
 
To forestall
 
imitative activity and strengthen patent rights, firms often attempt to create a ‘patent
 
thicket,’ i.e. obtaining patents not just on one central product or process, but on a
 
host of related products or processes [11]. Firms that try to compete with the
 
inventing firm will find their attempts to duplicate the central product or process
 
blocked by the inventing firm’s grip on alternative technologies. Many of the firm’s
 
patents on related products or processes may never be used or licensed; such ‘sleeping
 
patents’ are held only to raise the costs of entry or imitation by potential rivals.
 
 
 
@article{holman2005biotechnology,
 
  title={Biotechnology's Prescription for Patent Reform},
 
  author={Holman, C.M.},
 
  journal={J. Marshall Rev. Intell. Prop. L.},
 
  volume={5},
 
  pages={i},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Holman (2005) - Biotechnologys Prescription For Patent Reform.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: 2005 patent reform act.
 
Before discussing some of the implications of specific reforms on biotechnology, I digress briefly with a few general observations regarding biotechnology’s patent reform agenda. First, to a large extent, it is apparent that biotechnology values patents primarily for their ability to attract investment, and thus, the perceptions of investors with respect to patent reform play a dominant role in shaping the biotechnology position. Second, despite the widely-expressed fear that a proliferation of patents would have a deleterious effect on biomedical research, one sees very little evidence of that concern coming from the industry itself. To the contrary, biotechnology is one of the staunchest defenders of a strong patent system, and generally evinces little enthusiasm for reforms that might address the problem of a “patent thicket.
 
serious threat to biotechnology research by creating a patent thicket, sometimes referred to as a “patent anticommons.”106 The theory is especially associated with articles published by Heller and Eisenberg in 1998, and Eisenberg and Rai in 2002.107 Proponents of the patent thicket hypothesis note that while patents traditionally were reserved for products, there has been an increasing tendency for biomedical researchers to patent upstream inventions, i.e., research tools and inputs
 
If in fact a patent thicket is significantly impeding biotechnology research and development, one might expect that organizations representing the interests of biotechnology, such as BIO, WARF, and Genentech, would be advocating for reforms that would address the problem. Indeed, the biotechnology industry has never been shy about advocating for legislative action to address its concerns.112 But instead, these groups tend to be among the most adamant defenders of the status quo and strong patent rights. One might infer from this that a patent thicket is not in fact substantially impeding biotechnology.
 
 
 
@article{holman2006clearing,
 
  title={Clearing a path through the patent thicket},
 
  author={Holman, C.},
 
  journal={Cell},
 
  volume={125},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={629--633},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Holman (2006) - Clearing A Path Through The Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Commentary: Biotech (plant seed?)
 
 
Upstream patents have been criticized
 
on a number of counts. For example,
 
it has been proposed that the proliferation
 
of patents covering research
 
tools has resulted in a “patent thicket,”
 
rendering it virtually impossible to
 
conduct biomedical research without
 
inadvertently infringing upon a host of
 
conflicting patent claims (Heller and
 
Eisenberg, 1998; Rai and Eisenberg,
 
2002). Although in theory a researcher
 
should be able to license the necessary
 
technology inputs, in practice it
 
is generally not feasible owing to the
 
large number of different patent holders,
 
each with their own licensing
 
agenda. Some patent holders will not
 
even consider licensing their technol
 
technology
 
to competitors, and in the U.S., a
 
patentee can virtually never be compelled
 
to grant a license.
 
The problem is exemplified by
 
the experience of the developers of
 
“golden rice,” a genetically modified
 
crop engineered to produce elevated
 
levels of vitamin A (Ye et al., 2000).
 
The project reportedly required
 
access to technology inputs covered
 
by over 70 different patents,
 
and licensing the required intellectual
 
property was viewed as a major
 
obstacle to achieving success (RAFI
 
communiqué, 2000). In the end,
 
the patent owners agreed to freely
 
license the necessary technologies,
 
probably because golden rice was
 
being developed for humanitarian
 
purposes to prevent blindness in
 
children in the developing world and
 
was not considered commercially
 
viable.
 
 
@article{holman2008trends,
 
  title={Trends in human gene patent litigation},
 
  author={Holman, C.M.},
 
  journal={Science},
 
  volume={322},
 
  number={5899},
 
  pages={198--199},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={American Association for the Advancement of Science},
 
  filename={Holman (2008) - Trends In Human Gene Patent Litigation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Commentary: Gene patents
 
 
3). Much of the focus
 
has been on the alleged detrimental impact of
 
gene patents on the development and availability
 
of diagnostic testing (1, 3, 4). Some have
 
postulated that a “thicket” of patents will impede
 
basic biomedical research and will stifle
 
development and utilization of technologies
 
that involve the use of multiple genetic
 
sequences; DNA microarrays are a prime
 
example (5, 6). Others claim that gene patents
 
are uniquely difficult to design around and,
 
thus, fundamentally more restrictive of followon
 
developments than “traditional” patents (6)
 
 
@article{holman2012debunking,
 
  title={Debunking the myth that whole-genome sequencing infringes thousands of gene patents},
 
  author={Holman, C.M.},
 
  journal={Nature biotechnology},
 
  volume={30},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={240--244},
 
  year={2012},
 
  publisher={Nature Publishing Group},
 
  filename={Holman (2012) - Debunking The Myth That Whole Genome Sequencing Infringes Thousands Of Gene Patents.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Nature: Whole Gene Sequencing
 
 
Doesn't mention thickets - but explicitly debunks that there is one with respect to WGS (whole-genome
 
sequencing)
 
 
The assumption that 20% of human genes are
 
patented, and that as a consequence WGS will
 
inevitably result in the infringement of thousands
 
of gene patents, is based on a gross misinterpretation
 
of a single Science article. My
 
analysis of the claims from a substantial sampling
 
of the patents which form the basis for the
 
Jensen & Murray article indicates that the vast
 
majority of these patents would almost certainly
 
not be infringed by WGS, either because
 
they are not gene patents at all, or because they
 
only claim isolated DNA molecules unlikely to
 
be produced in WGS (e.g., long sequences and/
 
or cDNA sequences), or methods of genetic
 
testing that would not encompass WGS.
 
 
@article{horn2003alternative,
 
  title={Alternative approaches to IP management: One-stop technology platform licensing},
 
  author={Horn, L.},
 
  journal={Journal of commercial biotechnology},
 
  volume={9},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={119--127},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={Palgrave Macmillan},
 
  filename={Horn (2003) - Alternative Approaches To IP Management.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Technology Platform licensing: MPEG LA: Standards, pools
 
 
By providing the marketplace with fair, reasonable, nondiscriminatory
 
access to a portfolio of worldwide essential patents under a single licence, this
 
example of a one-stop technology platform licensing programme enables widespread
 
implementation, interoperability and use of fundamental broad-based technologies covered by
 
many patents owned by many patent owners. This paper will: (1) present observations from
 
MPEG LA’s unique experience and perspective including a description of the necessary
 
elements and principles on which such efforts are based, what works and why; and (2) describe
 
efforts to apply this innovative licensing model to the biotechnology and pharmaceutical
 
industries within the larger context of historical patent pooling as a solution to biotechnology
 
bottlenecks.
 
 
But,
 
products and the standards on which they
 
are based increasingly rely upon many
 
patents owned by many patent owners.
 
Therefore, if the ‘thicket’2 of essential IP
 
rights underlying their use cannot be
 
accessed under reasonable terms and
 
conditions (eg cost) applied evenly to all
 
similarly situated competitors, the best of
 
standards often go unused.
 
 
@article{huang2009does,
 
  title={Does patent strategy shape the long-run supply of public knowledge? Evidence from human genetics},
 
  author={Huang, K.G. and Murray, F.E.},
 
  journal={Academy of Management Journal},
 
  volume={52},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={1193--1221},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Academy of Management},
 
  filename={Huang Murray (2009) - Does Patent Strategy Shape The Long Run Supply Of Public Knowledge.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Thickets: Human Genome CORE PAPER
 
 
In testing
 
whether this effect shapes contributions to public
 
knowledge, we relied on two characteristics that
 
define the patent landscape: “thickets” and “fragmentation.”
 
A patent thicket is “an overlapping set
 
of patent rights requiring those seeking to commercialize
 
new technology to obtain licenses from multiple
 
patentees” (Shapiro 2001:1). We measured
 
thickets as the number of patents claiming the same
 
set of (gene) knowledge inputs.
 
 
Hypothesis 5. The denser the thicket of patents
 
over knowledge claimed in a publication, the
 
more the patent thicket negatively impacts the
 
rate of follow-on publications.
 
 
Although the 2 percent difference provides
 
weak support for Hypothesis 5, the underlying
 
relationship between gene patent grant and
 
long-run public knowledge production is clearly
 
not linear in the number of gene patents and does
 
not increase smoothly with thicket density.
 
 
Hypothesis 6. The greater the ownership fragmentation
 
of patents over knowledge claimed
 
in a publication, the more the fragmentation
 
negatively impacts the rate of follow-on
 
publications.
 
 
We therefore turned to an analysis of the ownership
 
fragmentation of such patent thickets to examine
 
whether ownership complexity contoured the
 
impact of patents on long-run knowledge production.
 
When we analyzed the impact of increase in
 
fragmentation in model 5 of Table 7, we found
 
strong support for Hypothesis 6. Specifically, over
 
and above the baseline decline in expected citations
 
of 5 percent (also see model 3, Table 6), there
 
is an incremental 7 percent decline (p � .05) in
 
follow-on knowledge production for every unit
 
increase in fragmentation of the patent thicket (relative
 
to the mean and in absolute terms).19
 
 
 
 
@article{hussinger2006silence,
 
  title={Is silence golden? Patents versus secrecy at the firm level},
 
  author={Hussinger, K.},
 
  journal={Economics of Innovation and New Technology},
 
  volume={15},
 
  number={8},
 
  pages={735--752},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Taylor \& Francis},
 
  filename={Hussinger (2006) - Is Silence Golden Patents Versus Secrecy At The Firm Level.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Trade Secrets!
 
 
The focus is on product innovating firms in German manufacturing in 2000.
 
The Mannheim Innovation Panel (MIP) and patent information from the
 
German Patent and Trademark Office constitute the data base. In 2000, the
 
MIP identifies firms that use patents and firms that use secrecy as a means
 
of protecting their IP. The importance of patents and secrecy is proxied by
 
the protected inventions’ success in the market, which is ultimately reflected
 
in figures of sales with new products. Using tobit and instrumental variables
 
regression a significant positive correlation between patenting and sales with
 
new products turns out, whereas there is no effect for secrecy.
 
This finding is in line with the hypothesis that for product innovating firms
 
patenting is the more important method to protecting inventions in their
 
market phase as opposed to secrecy, even though over the recent years a
 
more strategic use of patenting has gained in importance. This result is
 
confirmed by survey evidence in the same year suggesting that patents are
 
more important than secrecy to protect IP from the firms’ point of view.
 
The frequent use of secrecy may be explained by its protective value for
 
early-stage inventions.
 
 
A further development is that patents gained in value by their ability to
 
be linked with other patents, which encourages patenting of marginal inventions.
 
The resulting complex network of single patents that bears many legal
 
pitfalls for patent applicants was given the name ‘patent thicket’ (Shapiro,
 
2001). These developments put into question an increased number of patents
 
motivated by an increased need for IP protection and hint at the strategic
 
value of patents to have driven the patent surge.
 
To summarize: on the one hand, recent changes in patenting schemes have
 
caused an elevated need for patents as an IP protection tool. On the other
 
hand, they gained in importance as strategic instruments.
 
 
@article{huys2009legal,
 
  title={Legal uncertainty in the area of genetic diagnostic testing},
 
  author={Huys, I. and Berthels, N. and Matthijs, G. and Van Overwalle, G.},
 
  journal={Nature biotechnology},
 
  volume={27},
 
  number={10},
 
  pages={903--909},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Nature Publishing Group},
 
  filename={Huys (2009) - Legal Uncertainty In The Area Of Genetic Diagnostic Testing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology/Law: Genetic Diagnostic Testing
 
 
Different stakeholders have
 
expressed concerns about the effect of ‘blocking
 
patents’ or ‘patent thickets’ on genetic
 
technology, arguing that because such claims
 
are difficult or impossible to circumvent,
 
they would increase genetic testing prices
 
and hinder innovation2,3. The debate has
 
been directed towards the creation of possible
 
solutions for the potential “tragedy of
 
the anticommons” and several collaborative
 
licensing models have been proposed4
 
 
As this study shows that not that many
 
blocking gene patents exist, proposals aiming
 
at banning patents on human genes do
 
not provide a plausible solution24, unless the
 
ban would be on patents for broad genetic
 
diagnostic methods as such. For instance,
 
the European Society of Human Genetics
 
(Vienna) has recently recommended avoiding
 
patenting of the pure link between a
 
mutation and disease2. More attention
 
should be paid to the licensing practices in a
 
‘responsible’ way16,35,36. Otherwise, the risk
 
exists that the control by owners of patents
 
containing those broad claims with respect to
 
genetic diagnostic testing may in the future
 
dissociate actual genetic diagnostic testing
 
from genetic counseling and clinical investigation,
 
which is to the detriment of progress
 
of the genetic diagnostic service and public
 
healthcare system.
 
 
 
@article{iyama2005uspto,
 
  title={The USPTO's proposal of a biological research tool patent pool doesn't hold water},
 
  author={Iyama, S.},
 
  journal={Stanford Law Review},
 
  pages={1223--1241},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Iyama (2005) - The Usptos Proposal Of A Biological Research Tool Patent Pool Doesnt Hold Water.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Patent Pools: USPTO Biological Research Tools
 
 
2 Specifically, IP rights to research tools can limit the viability of particular research scenarios because of the phenomenon known as patent thicketing.3 Patent thickets arise because of well-distributed and overlapping patent rights. Thus, a given research process will be adversely affected where a would-be investigator encounters difficulty in the assembly of utilization rights for each research tool required for the particular research scheme.4 To mitigate this problem of patent thicketing, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) issued a white paper arguing for the creation of a patent pool, composed of biological research tools, to mechanically facilitate a broad licensing scheme of the necessary use rights.
 
 
@article{jacob2009patents,
 
  title={Patents and Pharmaceuticals},
 
  author={Jacob, Robin},
 
  year={2009},
 
  journal={A paper given on 29th November at the Presentation of the Directorate-General of Competition’s Preliminary Report of the Pharma-sector inquiry},
 
  filename={Jacob (2009) - Patents And Pharmaceuticals.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Public Sector Inquiry: Pharma
 
 
I wish to emphasise that the phenomenon of evergreening is not confined to the
 
pharma field. Nor is it new. Far from it. Every patentee of a major invention is likely to
 
come up with improvements and alleged improvements to his invention. By the time his
 
main patent has expired there will be a thicket of patents intended to extend his monopoly.
 
Some will be good, others bad. It is in the nature of the patent system itself that this should
 
happen and it has always happened. There is nothing new about “evergreening”, only the
 
name and the implication which flows from the word, that there is something sinister going on
 
and that it has only recently been discovered. My quotation from Blanco White shows this.
 
I would add that the particular figure of “up to 1,300” patents for a cluster needs more detail.
 
I do not believe it to be typical. In any event one one needs to divide the figure by 27 (for the
 
membership of the EU).
 
 
@article{jensen2004achieving,
 
  title={Achieving the optimal power of patent rights},
 
  author={Jensen, P.H. and Webster, E.},
 
  journal={Australian Economic Review},
 
  volume={37},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={419--426},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Jensen Webster (2004) - Achieving The Optimal Power Of Patent Rights.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Patent system: Designing one!
 
 
Not copyable. Some mention of thickets. Strange def.
 
 
 
@article{joshi2011strategic,
 
  title={When do strategic alliances inhibit innovation by firms? Evidence from patent pools in the global optical disc industry},
 
  author={Joshi, A.M. and Nerkar, A.},
 
  journal={Strategic Management Journal},
 
  volume={32},
 
  number={11},
 
  pages={1139--1160},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Joshi Nerkar (2011) - When Do Strategic Alliances Inhibit Innovation By Firms.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Mgmt: Patent Pools
 
 
No mention of thickets
 
 
Research and development (R&D) consortia are specialized strategic alliances that shape the
 
direction and scope of firm innovation activities. Little research exists on the performance consequences
 
of participating in R&D consortia. We study the effect of patent pools, a unique form of
 
R&D consortia, on firm performance in innovation. While prior research on alliances generally
 
implies that patent pools enhance firm innovation, our study finds the opposite. Analyzing data on
 
systemic innovation in the global optical disc industry, we find that patent pool formation substantially
 
and significantly decreases both the quantity and quality of patents subsequently generated
 
by licensors and licensees relative to the patenting activity of nonparticipants. Our empirical
 
findings suggest that patent pools actually inhibit, rather than enhance, systemic innovation by
 
participating firms.
 
 
@article{kato2004patent,
 
  title={Patent pool enhances market competition},
 
  author={Kato, A.},
 
  journal={International Review of Law and Economics},
 
  volume={24},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={255--268},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Kato (2004) - Patent Pool Enhances Market Competition.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: patent pools: substitutes inc. welfare
 
 
He considers the
 
role of patent pools in “patent thicket,” which means that there are so many patents issued
 
that a single newpatent will likely infringe on some other patents. This situation discourages
 
and retards research, development and commercialization. His paper concentrates on the
 
A. Kato / International Review of Law and Economics 24 (2004) 255–268 257
 
complements problem and claims that cross-licensing or patent pools may alleviate this
 
problem.
 
 
@article{kesselheim2005university,
 
  title={University-based science and biotechnology products},
 
  author={Kesselheim, A.S. and Avorn, J.},
 
  journal={JAMA: the journal of the American Medical Association},
 
  volume={293},
 
  number={7},
 
  pages={850--854},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={Am Med Assoc},
 
  filename={Kesselheim Avorn (2005) - University Based Science And Biotechnology Products.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: University Science, Biotech and pharma
 
 
Private corporations
 
can then commercialize these
 
insights by designing and marketing
 
new therapeutics or other medical technologies
 
based on them. In this chain
 
of development, allowing patenting of
 
each incremental innovation could risk
 
generating a dense thicket of overlapping
 
intellectual rights and thus hinder
 
research efforts. However, restricting
 
patenting rights to the end product
 
alone ignores earlier scientific and financial
 
contributions. Where intellectual
 
property law draws the line has billiondollar
 
ramifications for universities and
 
academic medical centers attempting to
 
support their research budgets, for
 
patients who depend on the creation of
 
innovative medical products, and for
 
society, which ultimately benefits from
 
and pays for these discoveries.
 
 
@article{kieff2011removing,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Removing Property from Intellectual Property and (Intended?) Pernicious Impacts on Innovation and Competition},
 
  author = {Kieff, F. Scott},
 
  journal = {Supreme Court Economic Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {19},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {January 2011},
 
  pages = {pp. 25-50},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/664561},
 
  ISSN = {07369921},
 
  abstract = {Commentators have poured forth a loud and sustained outcry over the past few years that sees property rule treatment of intellectual property (IP) as a cause of excessive transaction costs, thickets, anticommons, hold-ups, hold-outs, and trolls, which unduly tax and retard innovation, competition, and economic growth. The popular response has been to seek a legislative shift towards some limited use of weaker, liability rule treatment, usually portrayed as “just enough” to facilitate transactions in those special cases where the bargaining problems are at their worst and where escape hatches are most needed. This essay is designed to make two contributions. First, it shows how a set of changes in case law over just the past few years have hugely re-shaped the patent system from having several major, and helpful, liability-rule pressure-release valves, into a system that is fast becoming almost devoid of significant property rule characteristics, at least for those small entities that would most need property rule protection. The essay then explores some harmful effects of this shift, focusing on the ways liability rule treatment can seriously impede the beneficial deal-making mechanisms that facilitate innovation and competition. The basic intuition behind this bad effect of liability rules is that they seriously frustrate the ability for a market-challenging patentee to attract and hold the constructive attention of a potential contracting party (especially one that is a larger more established party) while preserving the option to terminate the negotiations in favor of striking a deal with a different party. At the same time, liability rules can have an additional bad effect of helping existing competitors to coordinate with each other over ways to keep out new entrants. The essay is designed to contribute to the literature on IP in particular, as well as the broader literatures on property and coordination, by first showing how a seemingly disconnected set of changes to the legal rules impacting a particular legal regime like the patent system can have unintended and sweeping harmful consequences, and then by exploring why within the more middle range of the spectrum between the two poles of property rules and liability rules, a general shift towards the property side may be preferred by those seeking an increase in access and competition.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2011},
 
  publisher = {The University of Chicago Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2011 The University of Chicago Press},
 
  filename={Kieff (2011) - Removing Property From Intellectual Property And Intended.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Property rules and legal regime
 
 
The essay is
 
designed to contribute to the literature on IP in particular,
 
as well as the broader literatures on property and coordination,
 
by fi rst showing how a seemingly disconnected set of
 
changes to the legal rules impacting a particular legal regime
 
like the patent system can have unintended and sweeping
 
harmful consequences, and then by exploring why within the
 
more middle range of the spectrum between the two poles of
 
property rules and liability rules, a general shift towards the
 
property side may be preferred by those seeking an increase in
 
access and competition.
 
 
In the vast majority of the intellectual property (IP) literature,
 
property rule treatment of IP is said to cause excessive transaction
 
costs, thickets, anticommons, hold-ups, hold- outs, and trolls,
 
unduly taxing and retarding innovation, competition, and economic
 
growth.5 The popular view of IP for the past several years has been
 
that property rule treatment is stopping deals from getting done, leaving
 
desired users of IP subject matter unable to engage in suffi cient
 
productive activities.
 
 
@article{kim2004vertical,
 
  title={Vertical structure and patent pools},
 
  author={Kim, S.H.},
 
  journal={Review of Industrial Organization},
 
  volume={25},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={231--250},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Springer},
 
  filename={Kim (2004) - Vertical Structure And Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: patent Pools: complements
 
 
The proliferation of fragmented and overlapping patent rights is increasingly
 
being recognized as a serious problem; referred to as a ‘‘patent thicket’’ (or
 
‘‘anticommons’’ by Heller and Eisenberg, 1998). Besides the additional
 
transaction costs incurred in navigating a patent thicket, Shapiro (2001) has
 
called attention to another source of inefficiency – the complements problem.
 
 
 
@article{king2007clearing,
 
  title={Clearing the Patent Thicket: The Supreme Court and Congress Undertake Patent Reform},
 
  author={King, S.M.},
 
  journal={Intell. Prop. \& Tech. LJ},
 
  volume={9},
 
  pages={13--13},
 
  year={2007},
 
  filename={King (2007) - Clearing The Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Patent Reform
 
 
All
 
three developments have led to what is perceived as a
 
marked increase in junk patents, as well as what Carl
 
Shapiro has termed a “patent thicket”—overlapping
 
sets of patent rights leading to a maze of cross-licensing
 
agreements, as well as the rise of hold-up litigation.
 
 
@article{kwon2012patent,
 
  title={Patent Thicket, Secrecy, and Licensing},
 
  author={Kwon, I.},
 
  journal={The Korean Economic Review},
 
  volume={28},
 
  number={1},
 
  pages={27--49},
 
  year={2012},
 
  filename={Kwon (2012) - Patent Thicket Secrecy And Licensing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Race for complementary patents
 
 
However, as new products
 
increasingly depend on more complex and complementary technologies, there exist
 
growing concerns that stronger patent protection may allow a single patent holder
 
to prevent other firms from commercializing all their new products that rely on that
 
patent, and discourage innovation as a consequence, called the hold-up problem (e.g.,
 
Hall and Ziedonis 2001, Parchomovsky and Wagner 2005, Shapiro 2001)
 
 
Note, however, that such hold-up problems can be solved or significantly
 
diminished through licensing contracts, because the owners of complementary
 
patents stand to lose their profits under the hold-up situation. Then, one can argue
 
that with licensing contracts, stronger patent protection should encourage
 
innovation even when firms compete for complementary patents, called a patent
 
thicket.
 
 
@article{lanjouw2004protecting,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Protecting Intellectual Property Rights: Are Small Firms Handicapped?},
 
  author = {Jean O. Lanjouw and Mark Schankerman},
 
  journal = {Journal of Law and Economics},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {47},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {April 2004},
 
  pages = {pp. 45-74},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/380476},
 
  ISSN = {00222186},
 
  abstract = {Abstract This paper studies the determinants of patent suits and settlements during 1978–99 by linking information from the U.S. patent office, the federal courts, and industry sources. We find that litigation risk is much higher for patents that are owned by individuals and firms with small patent portfolios. Patentees with a large portfolio of patents to trade, or other characteristics that facilitate “cooperative” resolution of disputes, are much less likely to prosecute infringement suits. However, postsuit outcomes do not depend on these characteristics. These findings show that small patentees are at a significant disadvantage in protecting their patent rights because their greater litigation risk is not offset by more rapid resolution of their suits. Our empirical estimates of the heterogeneity in litigation risk can help in developing private patent litigation insurance to mitigate the adverse affects of high enforcement costs.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2004},
 
  publisher = {The University of Chicago Press for The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago and The University of Chicago Law School},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2004 The University of Chicago},
 
  filename={Lanjouw Schankerman (2004) - Protecting Intellectual Property Rights Are Small Firms Handicapped.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Econ: Empirical: Patent litigation incidence
 
 
Thicket in footnote only
 
 
We find that litigation risk is much higher for patents that are owned by
 
individuals and firms with small patent portfolios. Patentees with a large portfolio
 
of patents to trade, or other characteristics that facilitate “cooperative” resolution of
 
disputes, are much less likely to prosecute infringement suits. However, postsuit
 
outcomes do not depend on these characteristics. These findings show that small
 
patentees are at a significant disadvantage in protecting their patent rights because
 
their greater litigation risk is not offset by more rapid resolution of their suits.
 
 
 
@techreport{lampe2009patent,
 
  title={Do patent pools encourage innovation? Evidence from the 19th-century sewing machine industry},
 
  author={Lampe, R.L. and Moser, P.},
 
  year={2009},
 
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Lampe Moser (2009) - Do Patent Pools Encourage Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Pools (historic)
 
 
Thickets in many footnotes, not in main body
 
 
@techreport{lampe2012patent,
 
  title={Do patent pools encourage innovation? Evidence from 20 US Industries under the New Deal},
 
  author={Lampe, R.L. and Moser, P.},
 
  year={2012},
 
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Lampe Moser (2012) - Do Patent Pools Encourage Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Pools (historic)
 
 
We also investigate whether part of the observed decline may be driven by a
 
reduction in lower-quality or “strategic” patents. For example, the creation of a pool may
 
reduce the need for member firms to create patent thickets by reducing the threat of
 
litigation (e.g., Shapiro 2001; Gilbert 2004)
 
 
Good refs?
 
 
@article{layne2011join,
 
  title={To join or not to join: examining patent pool participation and rent sharing rules},
 
  author={Layne-Farrar, Anne and Lerner, Josh},
 
  journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization},
 
  volume={29},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={294--303},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={LayneFarrar Lerner (2011) - To Join Or Not To Join.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Patent Pools: Vert Int and symmetry lead to joining, large founding groups and numeric prop. sharing rules don't
 
 
In recognition that participation in modern patent pools is voluntary, we present empirical evidence on
 
participation rates and the factors that drive the decision to join a pool, including the profit sharing rules
 
adopted by the pool's founders. In most participation contexts, the at-risk group is extremely difficult, if not
 
impossible, to identify. For pools centered on technologies that result from a standard-setting process, in
 
contrast, we are able to identify a relatively unambiguous population of patents eligible for inclusion but that
 
have not been included in the pool. We find that vertically integrated firms, with patents and downstream
 
operations, are more likely to join a patent pool and among those firms that do join, those with relatively
 
symmetric patent contributions (in terms of value) to a standard appear more likely to accept numeric
 
patent share rules for dividing royalty earnings.
 
 
Following on the
 
heels of the intense interest in the theories of “patent thickets” and
 
“royalty stacking” (e.g., Shapiro, 2001, 2006), and the increased
 
proliferation of organizations that promulgate technical standards for
 
products and services, patent pools are emerging as an important topic
 
for economic analysis.
 
 
@article{layne2007pricing,
 
  title={Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard-Setting Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments},
 
  author={Layne-Farrar, A. and Padilla, A.J. and Schmalensee, R.},
 
  journal={Antitrust LJ},
 
  volume={74},
 
  pages={671},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={LayneFarrar (2007) - Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard-Setting Organizations.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Pricing Licenses in SSOs
 
 
It would thus exacerbate any worries over patent proliferation and patent thickets, already a hotly debated in the
 
academic literature and popular press.
 
 
@article{leaffer2009patent,
 
  title={Patent Misuse and Innovation},
 
  author={Leaffer, M.},
 
  journal={J. High Tech. L.},
 
  volume={10},
 
  pages={142},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Leaffer (2009) - Patent Misuse And Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Patents vs. antitrust
 
 
Single company
 
acquisition of a dense web of overlapping patents-patent
 
thickets 15-may create a seemingly impenetrable web which a
 
company must hack its way through in order to commercialize
 
new technology.16
 
 
A firm with a
 
large patent portfolio enveloping a competitor's key
 
technologies-one that could be termed a "patent thicket"-has
 
the potential to use it to suppress competition in the ultimate
 
goods market
 
 
Whether patent misuse should exist independently from
 
the antitrust inquiry is a question of vigorous debate. As the
 
above discussion demonstrates, this issue has been
 
enthusiastically debated on both sides, where Congress and
 
particularly the Federal Circuit have called into question the
 
misuse doctrine's independent existence
 
 
@article{lee2006examining,
 
  title={Examining the Viability of Patent Pools for the Growing Nanotechnology Patent Thicket},
 
  author={Lee, A.},
 
  journal={Nanotech. L. \& Bus.},
 
  volume={3},
 
  pages={317},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Lee (2006) - Examining The Viability Of Patent Pools For The Growing Nanotechnology Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt: Patent pools in Nanotech
 
 
Patent pool can be more formally defined as “the aggregation of intellectual property rights which are the subject of cross-licensing, whether they are transferred directly by patentee to licensee or through some medium, such as a joint venture, set up specifically to administer the patent pool”.26 They are often viewed as the “simplest solution” to intellectual property rights (IPR) bottlenecks with multiple stakeholders that have overlapping sets of IP (a.k.a patent thickets) or are uncertain if there is possible infringement of patent issues (a.k.a. Patent Hold-Up).27
 
 
@article{lei2009patents,
 
  title={Patents versus patenting: implications of intellectual property protection for biological research},
 
  author={Lei, Z. and Juneja, R. and Wright, B.D.},
 
  year={2009},
 
  filename={Lei Juneja Wright (2009) - Patents Versus Patenting.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: (Nature): Academic biological research and patents
 
 
Our respondents do not encounter an anticommons
 
or a patent thicket. Rather, they
 
believe that institutionally mandated MTAs put
 
sand in the wheels of a lively system of intradisciplinary
 
exchanges of research tools. Seeing
 
no countervailing effect on the supply of these
 
tools, they conclude that patenting impedes the
 
progress of research.
 
 
@article{lemley2005patenting,
 
  title={Patenting nanotechnology},
 
  author={Lemley, M.A.},
 
  journal={Stanford Law Review},
 
  pages={601--630},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Lemley (2005) - Patenting Nanotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion: Nanotech
 
 
Some fear that ownership of nanotechnology patents is too fragmented, risking the development of a patent "thicket."77 Miller offers several examples of nanoscale technologies that have overlapping patents covering the same basic invention, including the carbon nanotube and semiconducting nanocrystals.78 Others point to similar overlaps involving drug delivery nanoparticles.7 Further, companies that want to use nanotechnology to produce products may need to use a range of different building-block inventions - for example, using patented atomic force microscopes to detect and align atoms into patented materials that are then manipulated into patented structures used in constructing a patented end product. If each step has one or perhaps several different patents, all owned by different people, the company will need a lot of licenses.
 
 
@article{lemley2007ten,
 
  title={Ten things to do about patent holdup of standards (and one not to)},
 
  author={Lemley, M.A.},
 
  journal={BCL Rev.},
 
  volume={48},
 
  pages={149},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Lemley (2007) - Ten Things To Do About Patent Holdup Of Standards And One Not To.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Discussion/Policy: SSOs and patent hold-up
 
 
Thicket in footnote only
 
 
@article{lemley2005probabilistic,
 
  title={Probabilistic Patents},
 
  author={Lemley, M.A. and Shapiro, C.},
 
  journal={The Journal of Economic Perspectives},
 
  volume={19},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={75--98},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Lemley Shapiro (2005) - Probabilistic Patents.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Probabilistic Patents!
 
 
Patent owners also improve their chance of winning the patent lottery by filing
 
multiple patents on closely related technologies, thereby increasing the chance that
 
their patents will cover technology that becomes widely adopted by market participants.
 
In a number of key industries, particularly semiconductors (Hall and
 
Ziedonis, 2001) and computer software (Bessen and Hunt, 2004), companies file
 
numerous patent applications on related components that are integrated into a
 
single functional product. The result is a "patent thicket," in which hundreds of
 
This content downloaded on Mon, 28 Jan 2013 19:30:04 PM
 
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
 
82 Journal of Economic Perspectives
 
patents can apply to a single product (Shapiro, 2001; FTC, 2003). If the holder of
 
a large patent portfolio asserts its patents against another company and claims that
 
the other company is infringing dozens or even hundreds of its patents, the target
 
company faces a very complex and costly undertaking if it chooses to fight all of
 
those patent infringement claims in court, knowing that it has to win all or nearly
 
all of the individual patent cases to avoid paying significant royalties or even being
 
enjoined from selling its product (Parchomovsky and Wagner, 2004).
 
 
Similarly, patent thickets can have deleterious effects on both competition and
 
innovation. One way to cut through the patent thicket is for incumbents with
 
extensive patent portfolios to enter into broad cross-licenses (that is, exchanges of
 
roughly symmetric patent positions) to "clear" the thicket. However, new entrants
 
who lack large patent portfolios may be at a major disadvantage in this situation
 
because they have no patents to trade. Without such cross-licenses, the result is
 
inefficient "royalty stacking," in which a manufacturer without its own patent
 
portfolio must pay royalties to a number of separate companies.6 Defensive patenting
 
is a natural, even inevitable, strategy in industries with patent thickets, but
 
defensive patenting itself can increase the density of the thicket.
 
 
@article{lemley2006patent,
 
  title={Patent holdup and royalty stacking},
 
  author={Lemley, M. and Shapiro, C.},
 
  year={2006},
 
  filename={Lemley Shapiro (2006) - Patent Holdup And Royalty Stacking.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Royalty stacking and hold-up
 
 
We have occasionally seen problems like this before, see Ted Sabety, Nanotechnology Innovation and
 
the Patent Thicket: Which IP Policies Promote Growth?, 15 Alb. L.J. Sci. & Tech. 477, 495-503 (2005)
 
(discussing example of radio patents in the 1920s), but they are much more common now than in the past.
 
 
Royalty stacking, patent thickets, and the related “anti-commons” problem have been a source of
 
concern in the semiconductor and biotechnology industries for some time.38 While the precise
 
extent of these problems remains unclear, empirical evidence of has mounted that royalty
 
stacking is far more than a theoretical possibility.
 
 
@article{lerner2003structure,
 
  title={The structure and performance of patent pools: empirical evidence},
 
  author={Lerner, J. and Strojwas, M. and Tirole, J.},
 
  journal={Working paper},
 
  year={2003},
 
  filename={Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2003) - The Structure And Performance Of Patent Pools Empirical Evidence.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Pools
 
 
Numerous commentators have suggested that
 
the proliferation of these awards has had socially detrimental consequences: overlapping
 
intellectual property rights may make it difficult for inventors to commercialize new
 
innovations. (Gallini [2002] reviews this literature.) Patent pools have been proposed by
 
Merges [1999], Shapiro [2000], and the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (Clark, et al.
 
[2001]) as a way in which firms can address these “patent thicket” problems.
 
 
@article{lerner2007design,
 
  title={The design of patent pools: The determinants of licensing rules},
 
  author={Lerner, J. and Tirole, J. and Strojwas, M.},
 
  journal={The RAND Journal of Economics},
 
  volume={38},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={610--625},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Lerner Tirole Strojwas (2007) - The Design Of Patent Pools The Determinants Of Licensing Rules.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Patent pool licensing
 
 
Identical quote to above, but different paper.
 
 
@article{lerner2005theeconomics,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {The Economics of Technology Sharing: Open Source and Beyond},
 
  author = {Lerner, Josh and Tirole, Jean},
 
  journal = {The Journal of Economic Perspectives},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {19},
 
  number = {2},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Spring, 2005},
 
  pages = {pp. 99-120},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/4134939},
 
  ISSN = {08953309},
 
  abstract = {},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2005},
 
  publisher = {American Economic Association},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2005 American Economic Association},
 
  filename={Lerner Tirole (2005) - The Economics Of Technology Sharing Open Source And Beyond.pdf}
 
}
 
 
@techreport{lerner2002efficient,
 
  title={Efficient patent pools},
 
  author={Lerner, J. and Tirole, J.},
 
  year={2002},
 
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Lerner Tirole (2002) - Efficient Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Patent pools
 
 
Innovations in computer hardware, software, and biotechnology often build on a number of other innovations owned by a diverse set
 
of owners and as a result ?patent thicket" problems - overlapping patent claims that preclude
 
the adoption of new technologies - can be severe.1
 
 
There is now widespread agreement among policymakers and economists that patent pools
 
may beneÞt both intellectual property owners and consumers, provided that the pools include
 
patents that are complementary or blocking.
 
 
 
@incollection{lerner2008public,
 
  title={Public policy toward patent pools},
 
  author={Lerner, J. and Tirole, J.},
 
  booktitle={Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 8},
 
  pages={157--186},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={University of Chicago Press},
 
  filename={Lerner Tirole (2008) - Public Policy Toward Patent Pools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Policy: Pools (welfare)
 
 
the fundamental tension in
 
regulators' views of antitrust activities. Many observers have suggested
 
that patent-thicket problems?where key patents are widely held?af
 
fect many emerging industries. Patent thickets may lead to three prob
 
lems. First, royalty stacking may result: each individual patent holder
 
may charge a royalty that seems reasonable when viewed in isolation,
 
but together they represent an unreasonable burden. Second, even if
 
other firms agree to license their patents at a modest rate, a hold-out
 
problem may result if a single firm then sets a high license fee for its tech
 
nology Finally, the very process of arranging the needed licenses may
 
prove to be time consuming. Patent pools thus offer a one-stop shop
 
through which these problems can be avoided.
 
 
  
 
  @techreport{lerner2003cooperative,
 
  @techreport{lerner2003cooperative,
Line 2,879: Line 42:
  
 
DISCARD: Appears to be almost identical to: Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2003) - The Structure And Performance Of Patent Pools Empirical Evidence
 
DISCARD: Appears to be almost identical to: Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2003) - The Structure And Performance Of Patent Pools Empirical Evidence
 
@article{lerner2007impact,
 
  title={What is the impact of software patent shifts? Evidence from Lotus v. Borland},
 
  author={Lerner, J. and Zhu, F.},
 
  journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization},
 
  volume={25},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={511--529},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Lerner Zhu (2007) - What Is The Impact Of Software Patent Shifts.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Copyright and patents as substitutes in software
 
 
The environment is a complex one: many other changes,
 
such as the widespread dissemination of the Internet, may have differentially affected firms
 
during this period. While our result contradicts the claim by Bessen and Hunt (2004) that software
 
patents substitute for R&D at the firm level, increased reliance on patenting could at the same time
 
contribute to patent thickets that slow down overall innovation in the industry. Therefore, the
 
patent thicket problem – an overlapping set of patent rights requiring those seeking to
 
commercialize new technology obtain licenses from multiple patentees (Shapiro, 2001) – could
 
still exist
 
 
@article{lin2001research,
 
  title={Research Versus Development: Patent Pooling, Innovation and Standardization in the Software Industry},
 
  author={Lin, D.},
 
  journal={J. Marshall Rev. Intell. Prop. L.},
 
  volume={1},
 
  pages={i},
 
  year={2001},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Lin (2001) - Research Versus Development.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Patent pools in software
 
 
Despite the impressive pace of modern invention, commentators have observed a certain “patent thicket” effect that may be impeding what has become an increasingly difficult road to the commercialization of new technologies.1 Specifically, as new technologies build upon old technologies, they necessarily become increasingly complex, and as a result, are often subject to the protection of multiple patents, covering both the new cumulative technologies as well as old foundational technologies.2 The difficulties of acquiring licenses (e.g., hold-out problems) for all such patents has the potential to stifle the development and commercialization of these new technologies. As such, patent pooling, once condemned as facilitating antitrust violations in past
 
 
@article{lin2011licensing,
 
  title={Licensing Strategies in the Presence of Patent Thickets},
 
  author={Lin, L.},
 
  journal={Journal of Product Innovation Management},
 
  volume={28},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={698--725},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Lin (2011) - Licensing Strategies In The Presence Of Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Licensing strategies
 
 
On the other hand, patents already granted can
 
make the development of cumulative technologies
 
prohibitively expensive, especially when the innovator
 
needs to license patents held by many firms or
 
faces potential litigation from patent holders. Related,
 
and often overlapping, patents owned by many entities
 
are often described as ‘‘patent thickets’’ and researchers
 
have argued that patent thickets can be
 
detrimental to innovation, especially in information
 
industries such as software (see, among others, Heller
 
and Eisenberg, 1998; Lessig, 2001; Shapiro, 2001; Bessen
 
and Maskin, 2009). One notable, and perhaps
 
unexpected, example of high licensing costs for downstream
 
firms is Microsoft. As one of the largest software
 
companies, Microsoft needs to license many
 
patented software components from independent
 
software vendors (ISV). In 2005, Microsoft paid
 
about $1 billion to license intellectual property from
 
other companies while collecting only $100 million in
 
royalties on its own patents (Ricadela, 2006).
 
 
@article{liu2008internal,
 
  title={Internal sequential innovations: How does interrelatedness affect patent renewal?},
 
  author={Liu, K. and Arthurs, J. and Cullen, J. and Alexander, R.},
 
  journal={Research Policy},
 
  volume={37},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={946--953},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Liu (2008) - Internal Sequential Innovations.pdf}
 
}
 
 
However, research often assumes that a firm’s patented
 
innovations are independent from each other.We draw upon evolutionary economics and
 
suggest that some of a firm’s patents share important genealogical relationships, which we
 
refer to as internal sequential innovations.
 
 
With the
 
power of the intellectual regime, internal sequential innovations
 
offer a larger thicket of protection that can define
 
the underlying technologies in a set of overlapping patents.
 
That is, a sequence of patents revolving around the same
 
technological trajectory can define the intellectual property
 
more precisely and protect it with an enlarged degree
 
of coverage. The holder of such patented innovations can
 
thereafter exclude competitors from the collective scope of
 
the claims laid out in all of the sequential patents (Wagner
 
and Parchomovsky, 2005).
 
 
@techreport{llanes2009anticommons,
 
  title={Anticommons and optimal patent policy in a model of sequential innovation},
 
  author={Llanes, G. and Trento, S.},
 
  year={2009},
 
  institution={Harvard Business School},
 
  filename={Llanes Trento (2009) - Anticommons And Optimal Patent Policy In A Model Of Sequential Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Sequential innovation model with a thicket
 
 
As the number of inputs needed in research increases, the innovator
 
faces a patent thicket and is threatened by the possibility of
 
hold-up, namely the risk that a useful innovation is not developed because
 
of lack of agreement with the patent holders. This problem has
 
been dubbed the tragedy of the anticommons (Heller 1998, Heller and
 
Eisenberg 1998).
 
 
@article{macdonald2004means,
 
  title={When means become ends: considering the impact of patent strategy on innovation},
 
  author={Macdonald, S.},
 
  journal={Information Economics and Policy},
 
  volume={16},
 
  number={1},
 
  pages={135--158},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Macdonald (2004) - When Means Become Ends.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt: Strategy: Discussion: Strategic use of patents
 
 
Among the patent strategies
 
recommended by consultants are:
 
• patent in a thicket around key patents held by competitors
 
 
The costs of navigating through mazes of
 
overlapping patent rights – through patent thickets – are likely to be considerable
 
(Shapiro, 2001), and are likely to be an obstacle to innovation. In industries
 
where the pace of change is rapid, where innovation is complex and dependent on
 
information from a multitude of sources, patent problems once found pragmatic
 
solutions.
 
Mostly, your patents are used in horse trading. You come together and
 
say, �Here�s our portfolio.� In [the communications equipment] industry,
 
things all build on each other. We all overlap on each others� patents.
 
Eventually we come to some agreement. �You can use ours and we can
 
use yours�. (quoted in Cohen et al., 2000, p. 19)
 
 
@article{mallo2008patent,
 
  title={Patent-related barriers to market entry for generic medicines in the European Union: A review of weaknesses in the current European patent system and their impact on market access of generic medicines},
 
  author={Mallo, L. and Roox, K. and Pike, J. and Brown, A. and Becker, S. and Thaler, G.},
 
  journal={Journal of Generic Medicines: The Business Journal for the Generic Medicines Sector},
 
  volume={5},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={255--280},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={SAGE Publications},
 
  filename={Mallo (2008) - Patent Related Barriers To Market Entry For Generic Medicines In The European Union.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Pharma and Generic meds
 
 
Certain structural defi ciencies and weaknesses
 
in the current examination procedure,
 
however, result in the grant of patents of
 
variable quality, giving a patent owner /
 
originator company facing expiry of a basic
 
product patent the opportunity to create what
 
is known as a ‘ patent thicket ’ (see below). The
 
most obvious structural issues are discussed
 
below.
 
 
One of the strategies
 
employed is the use of follow-on patents on
 
nonessential features, a practice known as
 
evergreening. Originators fi le numerous
 
follow-on patent applications covering a drug
 
in the hope that at least one of them will be
 
granted and survive a litigation challenge. The
 
consequence of this is often an extensive
 
thicket or cloud of patents around a drug,
 
 
@article{mann2004myth,
 
  title={The myth of the software patent thicket},
 
  author={Mann, R.J.},
 
  journal={bepress Legal Series},
 
  pages={183},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={bepress},
 
  filename={Mann (2004) - The Myth Of The Software Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Mgmt: Software Patent Thicket CORE PAPER
 
 
It then presents
 
evidence about existing practices in the industry suggests that technology in fact is readily
 
available, rebutting the prominent claims of a patent “thicket” that is supposedly stifling
 
innovation in the industry. On the contrary, I argue, to the extent patents have an important effect
 
in the industry, it is an effect that inures primarily to the benefit of the smaller firms trying to find
 
a foothold from which they can compete.
 
 
The broadest form of the criticism – associated with Carl Shapiro and Larry Lessig –
 
argues that the rapid proliferation of software patents has created a “patent thicket” that
 
deters innovation, particularly by small firms that are not well placed to compete against
 
the portfolios of their larger and better-heeled competitors
 
 
Larry
 
Lessig presents it forcefully as a matter of truth that the proliferation of software patents
 
has created a patent “thicket” (Shapiro’s term)256 or an “anticommons” (a term Lessig
 
draws from Michael Heller’s work with Becky Eisenberg257). This concern also pervades
 
James Bessen’s work (by himself and with other co-authors).258 Specifically, the idea is
 
that there are so many overlapping patents in the industry that potential innovators cannot
 
readily obtain the approvals necessary to conduct their research.259
 
 
The idea of a “thicket” or “anticommons” in the software industry is difficult to
 
credit.261 When raised in my interviews, that thesis universally was rejected.262 The
 
basic premise of the model is that assets will go unused because of the costs of obtaining
 
the permissions necessary to use them.263 As discussed above, there is nothing
 
theoretically impossible about that outcome. The important question, however, is
 
whether this is in fact what has happened in the software industry.
 
 
@article{marco2008therole,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {The Role of Patent Rights in Mergers: Consolidation in Plant Biotechnology},
 
  author = {Marco, Alan C. and Gordon C. Rausser},
 
  journal = {American Journal of Agricultural Economics},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {90},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Feb., 2008},
 
  pages = {pp. 133-151},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/30139496},
 
  ISSN = {00029092},
 
  abstract = {Few empirical studies have addressed the impact of the patent system on industry structure. Using firm-level patent data for firms in plant biotechnology, we develop a measure of patent enforceability. Duration models show that patent statistics are useful predictors of the timing of consolidation and that patent enforceability is an important factor influencing the likelihood of consolidation. Acquisitions in plant biotechnology may be motivated by the enforcement of patent rights when firms have overlapping technologies; some merger activity may be explained by attempts to avoid mutually blocking technology, as exemplified by the case of Roundup Ready corn.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2008},
 
  publisher = {Oxford University Press on behalf of the Agricultural & Applied Economics Association},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2008 Agricultural & Applied Economics Association},
 
  filename={Marco Rausser (2008) - The Role Of Patent Rights In Mergers.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Patent rights in mergers in biotech
 
 
No real mention of thickets but uses past patent litigation etc.
 
 
@article{maskus2006reforming,
 
  title={Reforming US patent policy: getting the incentives right},
 
  author={Maskus, K.E.},
 
  journal={Innovations: Technology, Governance, Globalization},
 
  volume={1},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={127--153},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={MIT Press},
 
  filename={Maskus (2006) - Reforming Us Patent Policy Getting The Incentives Right.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Reforming patent policy
 
 
In addition to the costs of individual patents, researchers have to contend with
 
“patent thickets.” That is, complex technologies, such as biomedical research tools,
 
embody a number of technological inputs, many of which are patented. A different
 
company, in turn, could own each patent. Negotiating these thickets raises the cost of
 
securing rights. Weaker patent standards encourage patent proliferation and an
 
enlargement of the thickets for research in areas such as biotechnology, agricultural
 
chemicals, and pharmaceuticals.
 
 
@article{masur2010costly,
 
  title={Costly Screens and Patent Examination},
 
  author={Masur, J.S.},
 
  journal={Journal of Legal Analysis},
 
  volume={2},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={687--734},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Oxford University Press},
 
  filename={Masur (2010) - Costly Screens And Patent Examination.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Policy: Reforming the patent office - screening against low quality (crap paper?)
 
 
Third, there are patents of low private
 
value and low (or negative) social value; this class of patents includes
 
both discarded, unenforced patents that increase the search costs and
 
risk imposed on commercial firms—the ‘‘patent thicket,’’ in popular parlance
 
(Shapiro 2001)—and worthless, largely unenforceable patents usable
 
only for extracting nuisance settlements (see Section 2.2.).
 
 
As an initial matter, search and information costs for the
 
entering firm will be high regardless of whether these patents are ever
 
enforced, as the market entrant is forced to comb through a dense ‘‘patent
 
thicket’’ in order to ascertain the boundaries of existing property rights
 
(Ayres & Parchomovsky 2007, 6–17; Merges & Duffy 2007, 615–616). It
 
may also be difficult and costly for new firms to credibly signal necessary
 
third parties such as banks, investors, and customers that a set of threatening
 
patents are invalid, particularly when those third parties are not experts
 
in the relevant technologies.
 
Most significantly, nascent market participants might face higher up-front 28
 
costs if litigation uncertainties and information asymmetries force the firmto
 
pay small licensing fees or settlements to a series of patent-holders who
 
choose to file nuisance lawsuits
 
 
@article{mcafee2004barrier,
 
  title={What is a Barrier to Entry?},
 
  author={McAfee, R.P. and Mialon, H.M. and Williams, M.A.},
 
  journal={American Economic Review},
 
  pages={461--465},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={McAfee Mialon Williams (2004) - What Is A Barrier To Entry.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Definition of barriers to entry!
 
 
@article{menezes2004amodel,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {A Model of Seller Holdout},
 
  author = {Menezes, Flavio and Pitchford, Rohan},
 
  journal = {Economic Theory},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {24},
 
  number = {2},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Aug., 2004},
 
  pages = {pp. 231-253},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/25055812},
 
  ISSN = {09382259},
 
  abstract = {We model a buyer who wishes to combine objects owned by two separate sellers in order to realize higher value. Sellers are able to avoid entering into negotiations with the buyer, so that the order in which they negotiate is endogenous. Holdout occurs if at least one of the sellers is not present in the first round of negotiations. We demonstrate that complementarity of the buyer's technology is a necessary condition for equilibrium holdout. Moreover, a rise in complementarity leads to an increased likelihood of holdout, and an increased efficiency loss. Applications include patents, the land assembly problem, and mergers.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2004},
 
  publisher = {Springer},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2004 Springer},
 
  filename={Menezes Pitchford (2004) - A Model Of Seller Holdout.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of seller holdout
 
 
@article{meniere2008patent,
 
  title={Patent law and complementary innovations},
 
  author={M{\'e}ni{\`e}re, Y.},
 
  journal={European Economic Review},
 
  volume={52},
 
  number={7},
 
  pages={1125--1139},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Meniere (2008) - Patent Law And Complementary Innovations.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of complementary patent innovation
 
 
It is also
 
very frequent in ICT industries such as electronics, computer hardware and soft-
 
ware, where ?rms have to navigate "patent thickets" (Shapiro, 2001)
 
 
As regards complementary innovations, the optimal patenting rule depends
 
on a trade-o¤ between the pro?t loss due to scattered complementary patents,
 
and the possible bene?t of patent disclosure. The scattering of complementary
 
patents between di¤erent owners creates a double marginalization issue. Since
 
each patentee behaves as a monopolist, the Cournot (1838) theorem predicts
 
that prices do not maximize the ?rms?pro?ts (Shapiro, 2001; Lerner & Tirole,
 
2005)1 . The requirement that complementary innovations be bundled prior to
 
patenting can be a way to prevent this pro?t loss. However, small innovations are
 
not disclosed when innovations have to be bundled prior to patenting (Scotchmer
 
and Green, 1990). As a result, ?rms lose the possibility to quit the race after a
 
?rst innovation has been patented, which leads to R&D cost duplications.
 
I show that patent disclosure has a positive social e¤ect, although it does not
 
permit a fully e¢ cient coordination between ?rms. In this context, bundling
 
innovations prior to patenting can be more e¢ cient if innovations can be devel-
 
oped quickly. As I argue in the Conclusion, this condition is consistent with the
 
legal de?nition of the "inventive step" patentability requirement.
 
 
@article{merges1996contracting,
 
  title={Contracting into liability rules: Intellectual property rights and collective rights organizations},
 
  author={Merges, R.P.},
 
  journal={Cal L. Rev.},
 
  volume={84},
 
  pages={1293},
 
  year={1996},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Merges (1996) - Contracting Into Liability Rules.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Foundational 1996 article that claims thickets are already solved!
 
 
As intellectual property rights have gained in prominence, businesspeople
 
and scholars alike have complained of the increasing burden
 
of obtaining intellectual property licenses and, failing this,
 
litigating intellectual property disputes. Intellectual property experts,
 
especially scholars, have responded to this burgeoning thicket of rights
 
with a series of initiatives to expedite deal making by means of statutory
 
compulsory licensing. These licenses are classic examples of "liability
 
rulesh" in the foundational legal entitlements framework of Guido Calabresi
 
and A. Douglas Melamed. They appear to be a compromise:
 
they address the mushrooming transactional hurdle created by new and
 
stronger intellectual property rights, while preserving most of the economic
 
advantages that accompany strengthened rights. In this Article,
 
Professor Merges argues that proposals to create more compulsory licenses
 
are rooted in a faulty theoretical framework. Based on a survey
 
of the diverse institutions various industries have cultivated to handle
 
intellectual property transactions, Merges contends that "repeat players"
 
(individuals and firms that frequently need to exchange rights) can
 
and often do take steps to overcome transactional bottlenecks.
 
 
This Article is aimed at providing conceptual guidance for those
 
who need to traverse the new thicket of intellectual property rights
 
(IPRs).' Each vine, each plant, standing in one's path represents a distinct
 
IPR owned by an individual. To pass through, one needs a license
 
from each owner. Where a single right blocks the path, this is easy: a
 
single licensing contract does the trick. Today, however, business people
 
more often than not encounter a tangled, twisted mass of IPRs, which
 
criss-cross the established walkways of commerce. Progress along this
 
path does not come cheaply; rather, it requires numerous contracts with
 
multiple, independent right holders.
 
 
@article{merges2006introductory,
 
  title={Introductory Note to Brief of Amicus Curiae in eBay v. MercExchange},
 
  author={Merges, R.P.},
 
  journal={Berkeley Tech. LJ},
 
  volume={21},
 
  pages={997},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Merges (2006) - Introductory Note To Brief Of Amicus Curiae In Ebay V MercExchange.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Troll, injuction
 
 
This is commonly described as a "patent thicket": "a
 
dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must
 
hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology."
 
Carl Shapiro,
 
 
The patent thicket and other well-recognized inefficiencies in the current
 
patent system provide the raw material for patent trolls' machinations.
 
 
@article{mertes2010managing,
 
  title={Managing the patent thicket and maximizing patent lifetime in vaccine technology},
 
  author={Mertes, M.M.M. and St{\"o}tter, G.},
 
  journal={Human Vaccines},
 
  volume={6},
 
  number={10},
 
  pages={860--863},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Landes Bioscience},
 
  filename={Mertes Stotter (2010) - Managing The Patent Thicket And Maximizing Patent Lifetime In Vaccine Technology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Policy: Thickets in vaccines (short)
 
 
Managing the patent thicket in the
 
fields of vaccine technology is challenging
 
as one product may be covered by a
 
plurality of exclusive IP rights that have
 
to be considered when developing a
 
product and building up a patent portfolio.
 
Consequently, licensing is a key point
 
in the vaccine industry. If a basic patent is
 
held by a powerful patent holder refusing
 
to grant a license under reasonable commercial
 
terms or abuses a market-dominating
 
position, it should be examined,
 
whether the requirements to request a
 
compulsory license are fulfilled.
 
 
 
@article{meurer2002business,
 
  title={Business method patents and patent floods},
 
  author={Meurer, M.J.},
 
  journal={Wash. UJL \& Pol'y},
 
  volume={8},
 
  pages={309},
 
  year={2002},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Meurer (2002) - Business Method Patents And Patent Floods.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Business method patents
 
Furthermore, a thicket of patents may stultify development of
 
technology because of the cost of securing patent licenses from the
 
large numbers of patent owners.
 
 
I fear that customer service methods are especially likely
 
to create a patent thicket that slows cumulative innovation and
 
diffusion, and institutions like patent pools may not emerge to solve
 
these problems because of the uncertain valuation of these inventions
 
and the heterogeneity of the inventions and patent owners. Trade
 
secret law rather than patent law will often protect administrative
 
methods, so making them patentable subject matter might not have
 
significant effects.
 
 
@book{mossoff2009stitch,
 
  title={A stitch in time: The rise and fall of the sewing machine patent thicket},
 
  author={Mossoff, A.},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={George Mason University School of Law},
 
  filename={Mossoff (2009) - A Stitch In Time The Rise And Fall Of The Sewing Machine Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: History: 'First' Patent Thicket
 
 
Scholarly interest in how anticommons theory applies to patents has skyrocketed since
 
Professor Michael Heller first proposed a decade ago that excessively fragmented interests in
 
land can frustrate its commercial development. There is now a vigorous debate on whether
 
anticommons exist in patent law, and, if so, whether these “patent thickets” impede innovation in
 
patented products. This article contributes to this debate by analyzing the rise and fall of the first
 
patent thicket in American history: the “Sewing Machine War” of the 1850s. The invention of the
 
sewing machine in the antebellum era represents many firsts in the American legal system—the
 
first patent thicket, the first “patent troll,” and the first patent pool. Significantly, this case study
 
verifies that patent thickets exist and that they can frustrate commercial development of new
 
products. But it also challenges widely held assumptions in the patent thicket literature. Many
 
scholars believe that this is largely a modern problem arising from a host of allegedly new issues
 
in the patent system, such as incremental high-tech innovation, excessive litigation, and the rise
 
of “patent trolls.” Yet the sewing machine patent thicket exhibited all of these phenomena,
 
revealing that patent thickets have long existed within the historically successful American
 
patent system. The denouement of the sewing machine patent thicket in the Sewing Machine
 
Combination of 1856, the first privately formed patent pool, further challenges the widely held
 
belief that patent thickets are best solved through new statutes, regulations or court decisions
 
that limit property rights in patents. To the contrary, the Sewing Machine Combination was
 
formed against the backdrop of the strong protection of patent rights in the antebellum
 
era. Thus, the story of the invention of the sewing machine is a striking account of early
 
American technological, commercial and legal ingenuity, which heralds important empirical
 
lessons for how patent thicket theory is understood and applied today.
 
 
@article{mossoff2011rise,
 
  title={Rise and Fall of the First American Patent Thicket: The Sewing Machine War of the 1850s, The},
 
  author={Mossoff, A.},
 
  journal={Ariz. L. Rev.},
 
  volume={53},
 
  pages={165},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Mossoff (2011) - Rise And Fall Of The First American Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
See above. Possibly a later version?
 
 
When Michael Heller proposed that excessively fragmented property rights in land can frustrate its commercial development, patent scholars began debating whether Heller’s anticommons theory applies to property rights in inventions. Do ?patent thickets? exist? The rise and fall of the first American patent thicket—the Sewing Machine War of the 1850s—confirms that patent thickets do exist and that they can frustrate commercial development of new products. But this historical patent thicket also challenges the widely held assumption that this is a modern problem arising from allegedly new issues in the patent system, such as incremental high-tech innovation and the impact of ?patent trolls.? The Sewing Machine War exhibited all of these phenomena, proving that these are hoary issues in patent law. The denouement of this patent thicket in the Sewing Machine Combination of 1856, the first privately formed patent pool, further challenges the conventional wisdom that patent thickets are best solved through public-ordering regimes that limit property rights in patents. The invention and incredible commercial success of the sewing machine is a striking account of early American technological, commercial, and legal ingenuity, which heralds important empirical lessons for how patent thicket theory is understood and applied today.
 
 
@book{muris2001competition,
 
  title={Competition and intellectual property policy: The way ahead},
 
  author={Muris, T.J.},
 
  year={2001},
 
  publisher={US FTC},
 
  filename={Muris (2001) - Competition And Intellectual Property Policy The Way Ahead.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: FTC speech!
 
 
On the one hand, some observers believe that this patent explosion could injure competition by
 
making it more difficult for rival inventors to sell competing products. According to Professor Carl Shapiro, a
 
"patent thicket" has formed, which he describes as "a dense web of overlapping...
 
 
@article{murray2006when,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {When Ideas Are Not Free: The Impact of Patents on Scientific Research},
 
  author = {Murray, Fiona and Stern, Scott},
 
  journal = {Innovation Policy and the Economy},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {7},
 
  number = {},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {2006},
 
  pages = {pp. 33-69},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/25056189},
 
  ISSN = {15313468},
 
  abstract = {This chapter describes the impact of formal intellectual property rights on the production and diffusion of "dual knowledge"-ideas that are simultaneously of value as a scientific discovery and as a useful, inventive construct. We argue that a great deal of knowledge generated in academia, particularly in the life sciences, falls into this category (sometimes referred to as Pasteur's Quadrant). The production and diffusion of dual purpose knowledge challenges the premise of most science policy analysis, which is implicitly based on a clear separation between basic scientific knowledge and applied knowledge useful in the development of new technology. Instead, dual knowledge simultaneously makes both a basic and an applied contribution. We review qualitative and quantitative evidence relating to the policy challenges raised by the production and dissemination of dual knowledge, highlighting three broad findings. First, rather than facing a fundamental tradeoff between applied research and more fundamental scientific knowledge, research agencies can and do invest in dual purpose knowledge. Indeed, the dual purpose knowledge framework suggests a distinct rationale for public sector involvement in the funding and conduct of research: the social impact of a given piece of knowledge may be enhanced when knowledge is produced and disclosed in accordance with the norms of the scientific research community (particularly compared to secrecy). Second, we suggest that, within Pasteur's Quadrant, the increased use of formal IPR seems to be significantly shaping the structure, conduct and performance of both university and industry researchers. On the one hand, from the perspective of individual researchers, patenting does not seem to come at the expense of scientific publication, and both respond to the process of scientific discovery. There is some evidence, however, that patent grant may reduce the extent of use of knowledge: the citation rate to a scientific article describing a dual-purpose discovery experiences a modest decline after patent rights are granted over that knowledge. Finally, the impact of patents may be indirect; rather than directly impacting behavior through patent enforcement, scientific conduct may be affected through related mechanisms such as material transfer agreements. Not simply a legal document within a seamless web of cooperation, nor a bludgeon to stop scientific progress in its tracks, patents seem to be changing the "rules of the game" for scientific exchange, cooperation, and credit.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2006},
 
  publisher = {The University of Chicago Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2006 The National Bureau of Economic Research},
 
  filename={Murray Stern (2006) - When Ideas Are Not Free The Impact Of Patents On Scientific Research.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Discussion with some empirics: Effect on academic research of patents
 
 
In other
 
words, recent empirical evidence points to the presence of a "licensing
 
thicket": the proliferation of both patents and contractual mechanisms
 
such as MTAs limiting the exchange and diffusion of scientific research
 
materials and knowledge.
 
 
Overall, it is important to emphasize that each of these pieces of
 
empirical evidence should be treated with considerable caution: tracing
 
out the impact of policy and institutions on the creation and diffusion
 
of knowledge is a formidable task. This research is recent and a great
 
deal of further theoretical and empirical work remains to be done. With
 
these important caveats in mind, the empirical evidence to date does
 
seem to suggest that IPR and related institutions have real impacts on
 
the conduct and nature of research in Pasteur's Quadrant, and offers a
 
novel perspective on innovation policy, particularly in the life sciences.
 
 
@article{nagaoka2006empirical,
 
  title={An Empirical Assessment of the Effects of Patent Thickets},
 
  author={Nagaoka, S. and Nishimura, Y.},
 
  journal={unpublished, Hitotsubashi University},
 
  year={2006},
 
  filename={Nagaoka Nishimura (2006) - An Empirical Assessment Of The Effects Of Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: JUST ONE PAGE - APPEARS A CORE PAPER (though weak)
 
 
In this paper we assess empirically how a “patent thicket” affects the patenting
 
propensity and the use of the patents as well as whether it negatively affects the
 
appropriability of the R&D and patenting by a firm.
 
 
Our major findings are the following four: Firstly, a firm with higher sales per
 
capita tends to have a higher propensity to patent its inventions in an industry in
 
which there is extensive cross-licenses. Secondly, while a firm with extensive crosslicensing
 
has a lower rate of patent utilization, there is no evidence that a firm in an
 
industry with higher patent thicket has a lower rate of internally utilizing the granted
 
patents. Thirdly, a firm in an industry with higher patent thicket has a lower proportion
 
of blocking patents in the total granted patents. Fourthly, there is no strong evidence
 
that R&D spending or patent acquisition has a significantly lower effect on the firm’s
 
profitability for a firm in an industry with higher patent thicket.
 
 
@article{napoleon2009impact,
 
  title={Impact of Global Patent and Regulatory Reform on Patent Strategies for Biotechnology},
 
  author={Napoleon, V.J.},
 
  journal={Pitt. J. Tech. L. \& Pol'y},
 
  volume={9},
 
  pages={1},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Napoleon (2009) - Impact Of Global Patent And Regulatory Reform On Patent Strategies For Biotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Policy (badly written): patent reform in biotech
 
 
As we discussed, at the broadest level biotechnology is an industry that includes innovation and commercialization that are supported by patents. The breadth of patent filings and the issuance of patents on more basic discoveries are on the rise.
 
This pattern, however, has created what some would characterize as a “Patent Thicket”59 in biotechnology. That is, emerging from the overabundance of patent filings and associated activity is “a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights”60 that requires those seeking to commercialize new technology to obtain licenses from multiple patentees.61 Pharmaceutical companies typically grow a patent thicket seeking a wide range of chemical variants and analogs, methods of synthesizing the drug, chemical intermediates in this synthesis, different crystal forms, different finished dosage forms and various methods of use.62 Obtaining permission from various patent holders for use of patents can prove to be difficult particularly if the patent holder’s objective in creating the thicket is to block innovation by outsiders. Because useful innovation in biotechnology requires multiple inventive steps and technologies, we could conceivably witness cumulative innovation with infringement on many patents which ultimately serves as a drag on innovation and commercialization.
 
 
 
@article{nielsen2006compulsory,
 
  title={Compulsory Patent Licensing: Is It a Viable Solution in the United States},
 
  author={Nielsen, C.M. and Samardzija, M.R.},
 
  journal={Mich. Telecomm. \& Tech. L. Rev.},
 
  volume={13},
 
  pages={509},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Nielsen Samardzija (2006) - Compulsory Patent Licensing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Compulsory Licensing
 
 
Many of the patents overlap and block the use of other
 
patents, thereby creating a “patent thicket”—a “dense web
 
 
Patent trolls notwithstanding, the ability to bring a product to market
 
in the presence of a patent thicket and the stacking royalties must separately
 
be addressed. Patent clearinghouses (“PCHs”) and patent pools
 
have been proposed and utilized. Sometimes, however, patent owners
 
simply refuse to license the patent rights needed to produce a product—
 
particularly where the demand for a hefty royalty cannot be met or a
 
threat by a patent troll is involved.
 
To tackle the issue of obtaining a license from a non–practicing patentee,
 
such as a patent troll, or in the event that a patent owner wishes to
 
opt out of the PCH or patent pool, compulsory patent licensing may be a
 
viable, or only, solution
 
 
@article{noel2006strategic,
 
  title={Strategic patenting and software innovation},
 
  author={Noel, M.D. and Schankerman, M.},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Paper},
 
  filename={Noel Schankerman (2006) - Strategic Patenting And Software Innovation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Reduced form model with empirics. CORE PAPER
 
 
Strategic patenting is widely believed to raise the costs of innovating, especially in industries
 
characterised by cumulative innovation. This paper studies the effects of strategic patenting
 
on R&D, patenting and market value in the computer software industry. We focus on two key
 
aspects: patent portfolio size which affects bargaining power in patent disputes, and the
 
fragmentation of patent rights (.patent thickets.) which increases the transaction costs of
 
enforcement. We develop a model that incorporates both effects, together with R&D
 
spillovers. Using panel data for the period 1980-99, we find evidence that both strategic
 
patenting and R&D spillovers strongly affect innovation and market value of software firms.
 
 
In such industries, it is a widely held view that patenting
 
activity creates a ?thicket?of fragmented property rights that impedes R&D activity by constrain-
 
ing the ability of ?rms to operate without extensive licensing of complementary technologies.
 
 
There are four key empirical ?ndings in the paper. First, there are large, positive technology
 
spillovers from R&D for software ?rms. Second, we ?nd that patenting by technology rivals reduces
 
the ?rm?s R&D investment, patenting and market value. Third, greater concentration (less frag-
 
mentation) of patent rights among rivals reduces both R&D and patenting by the ?rm ?re?ecting
 
less need to have an arsenal of patents to resolve disputes when there are fewer players ?but it
 
increases market value because transaction costs are lower. Finally, we ?nd that there is a large
 
patent premium in the stock market valuation of these software ?rms, which accounts for about
 
twenty percent of the overall private returns to R&D investments.
 
 
@article{packalen2010complements,
 
  title={Complements and potential competition},
 
  author={Packalen, Mikko},
 
  journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization},
 
  volume={28},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={244--253},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Packalen (2010) - Complements And Potential Competition.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Underlying theory on licensing complements
 
 
In this paper we examine the effect of cooperation between complementary incumbent monopolists on
 
consumer welfare. While divided technical leadership makes it difficult for firms to integrate into
 
complementary markets, firms induce entry in complementary markets by reducing the cost of entry in
 
those markets. This is accomplished through, for example, the development and dissemination of royaltyfree
 
intellectual property. We present and analyze a model in which incumbents can influence the ease of
 
entry in complementary markets. Cooperation between complementary monopolists decreases consumer
 
welfare by reducing or even eliminating the entry inducement incentive but increases consumer welfare by
 
eliminating double marginalization. We show that cooperation may decrease consumer welfare, contrary to
 
Cournot's celebrated double monopoly result, and that the welfare comparison can be determined in terms
 
of straightforward economic concepts. We also present and analyze a model in which each incumbent can
 
induce entry in the complementary market through long-term price commitments which are common in
 
patent licensing.
 
 
@article{palangkaraya2011misclassification,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  Title = {Misclassification Between Patent Offices: Evidence From A Matched Sample Of Patent Applications},
 
  author = {Palangkaraya, Alfons and Webster, Elizabeth and Jensen, Paul H.},
 
  journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {93},
 
  number = {3},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {August 2011},
 
  pages = {pp. 1063-1075},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/23016095},
 
  ISSN = {00346535},
 
  abstract = {In this paper, we estimate the extent of misclassification in patent examination decisions between the European Patent Office (EPO) and the Japanese Patent Office (JPO), that is, applications that are incorrectly refused a patent or incorrectly granted a patent. Using a proxy for inventive step as the predictor of the correct decision, we find that the probability that a "true grant" application is refused is 6.1%, while the probability that a "true refusal" application is granted is 9.8%. However, we find no evidence of an increasing trend of granting "bad" patents at the EPO and JPO.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2011},
 
  publisher = {The MIT Press},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2011 The MIT Press},
 
  filename={Palangkaraya Webster Jensen (2011) - Misclassification Between Patent Offices.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Abstract—In this paper, we estimate the extent of misclassification in
 
patent examination decisions between the European Patent Office (EPO)
 
and the Japanese Patent Office (JPO), that is, applications that are incorrectly
 
refused a patent or incorrectly granted a patent. Using a proxy for
 
inventive step as the predictor of the correct decision, we find that the
 
probability that a ‘‘true grant’’ application is refused is 6.1%, while the
 
probability that a ‘‘true refusal’’ application is granted is 9.8%. However,
 
we find no evidence of an increasing trend of granting ‘‘bad’’ patents at
 
the EPO and JPO.
 
 
Second, our notion of a correct decision rests on the legal
 
meaning of validity (that is, novelty, nonobviousness, and
 
usefulness). From an economic perspective, however,
 
whether an invention should be patentable depends on the
 
relative net change to the incentive to invent and innovate
 
and the size of the deadweight monopoly losses. The latter
 
includes strategic ways to construct undesirable patent
 
thickets, build patent portfolios to extract additional bargaining
 
power in cross-licensing arrangements, or other
 
rent-seeking activities. Our estimated size of misclassification
 
effectively overlooks these issues. However, it is plausible
 
that the legal and economic interpretations of patent
 
validity are correlated.
 
 
@article{parchomovsky2005patent,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Patent Portfolios},
 
  author = {Gideon Parchomovsky and Wagner, R. Polk},
 
  journal = {University of Pennsylvania Law Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {154},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Nov., 2005},
 
  pages = {pp. 1-77},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/25047582},
 
  ISSN = {00419907},
 
  abstract = {},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2005},
 
  publisher = {The University of Pennsylvania Law Review},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2005 The University of Pennsylvania Law Review},
 
  filename={Parchomovsky Wagner (2005) - Patent Portfolios.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Patent Portfolio theory...
 
 
This article develops a comprehensive theory of patent value, responding to
 
growing empirical evidence that the traditional appropriability premise of pat
 
ents is fundamentally incomplete in the modern innovation environment. We
 
find that for patents, the whole is greater than the sum of its parts: the true
 
value of patents lies not in their individual worth, but in their aggregation into
 
a collection of related patents?a patent portfolio.
 
 
"Patent thickets" refer to the fact that in many areas of technology, great num
 
bers of related patents exist at any particular time, and many might have applicability
 
to any commercial product. See, e.g., Carl Shapiro, Navigating
 
 
The patent portfolio theory also predicts that certain components
 
of the cost of innovation will increase in the future. As we explained
 
above, to achieve an effective portfolio, firms must obtain a significant
 
number of related patents.212 The concentration of related patents in
 
the hands of certain firms will raise the information and transaction
 
costs associated with innovation. In a portfolio-driven environment,
 
innovators will be forced to spend more time acquiring information
 
about preexisting patents213 and negotiating licenses with their hold
 
ers. As several commentators have pointed out, in such a patent
 
intensive environment, one should also expect occasional holdup
 
problems and bargaining failures.214 As a result, innovation becomes
 
more costly, at least for firms that do not have strong patent portfolios
 
of their own.
 
The portfolio theory not only explains the existence of "patent
 
thickets," but also suggests that the problem is highly unlikely to go
 
away.
 
 
@article{paredes2006written,
 
  title={Written Description Requirement in Nanotechnology: Clearing a Patent Thicket},
 
  author={Paredes, J.P.},
 
  journal={J. Pat. \& Trademark Off. Soc'y},
 
  volume={88},
 
  pages={489},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Paredes (2006) - Written Description Requirement In Nanotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Nanotech: written description requirement
 
 
The
 
notion of a patent thicket is where an
 
overlapping set of patent rights requires
 
that those seeking to commercialize new
 
technology obtain licenses from multiple
 
patentees.6 If you get monopoly rights
 
down at the bottom, "you may stifle competition
 
that uses those patents later on
 
and so the breadth and utilization of
 
patent rights can be used not only to stifle
 
competition, but also have adverse effects
 
in the long run on innovation."7
 
 
Moreover, the quality of these
 
nanotechnology patents has been repeatedly
 
called into question," so the navigation
 
of a patent thicket will have to be
 
around these questionable patents.
 
 
One of the policy purposes of the written
 
description requirement has been the quid
 
pro quo of the patent bargain, which
 
requires the patentee to describe the
 
invention in such terms that any person
 
skilled in the art to which it pertains may
 
construct and use it after expiration of the
 
patent .6
 
 
became more clear that the
 
purpose of the written description
 
requirement is to "ensure that the scope of
 
the right to exclude, as set forth in the
 
claims, does not overreach the scope of
 
the inventor's contribution to the field of
 
art as described in the patent specification."
 
 
 
@article{pray2005innovation,
 
  title={Innovation and dynamic efficiency in plant biotechnology: An introduction to the researchable issues},
 
  author={Pray, C. and Oehmke, J.F. and Naseem, A.},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={AgBioForum},
 
  filename={Pray Oehmke Naseem (2005) - Innovation And Dynamic Efficiency In Plant Biotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Innovation and dyn. eff. in biotech
 
 
The agricultural biotechnology industry is characterized by
 
heavy investment in research and development, dynamic technical
 
change, and increasing concentration in both the output
 
market and the ownership of intellectual properties that support
 
ongoing innovation. This raises questions about the industry’s
 
ability to continue to deliver path-breaking innovations. This
 
paper lays out these questions, describes the relevant data
 
(including the newly available agricultural biotechnology intellectual
 
property database), and provides a conceptual framework
 
for addressing the questions. The empirical discussion and conceptual
 
framework in this paper constitute a structure upon
 
which the remaining articles in this issue build to address the
 
overall question of how best we can maintain socially desirable
 
rates of innovation and dynamic efficiency in plant biotechnology.
 
 
The 1990s witnessed legal challenges to many
 
key patents, complaints by scientists and industry that
 
they could not commercialize products that relied on
 
intellectual properties patented by private firms, record
 
numbers of mergers and acquisitions to integrate the
 
biotechnology and seed industries, and complex thickets
 
of interwoven patents that prevented even the most
 
skilled negotiators from obtaining rights to disseminate
 
innovative technologies. Industry responded by aggressively
 
consolidating, so that enabling intellectual properties
 
were owned by the same company, which could
 
then move forward with the commercialization of new
 
agricultural technologies.
 
 
As the technology has developed, patenting has
 
become increasingly widespread in every major area of
 
agricultural biotechnology. Every successive five-year
 
period has seen more patented innovation than the last
 
period—in every technology. It is unclear whether this
 
supports the anticommons/patent thicket concern.
 
 
@article{quillen2001continuing,
 
  title={Continuing patent applications and performance of the US patent and trademark office},
 
  author={Quillen, C.D. and Webster, O.H.},
 
  journal={Fed. Cir. BJ},
 
  volume={11},
 
  pages={1},
 
  year={2001},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Quillen Webster (2001) - Continuing Patent Applications And Performance Of The Us Patent And Trademark Office.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Empirical: Patent continuations
 
The United States is unique in permitting patent applicants to refile their
 
patent applications as continuation and continuation-in-part applications claiming
 
the benefit of the filing date of a prior application and restart the examination
 
process all over again. Data provided by the USPTO concerning continuing
 
application filings for its fiscal years 1993-1998 reveal that 28.4% of the utility,
 
plant, and reissue (UPR) applications filed in those years were not new or original
 
applications, but were continuing applications claiming the benefit of the filing
 
dates of previously filed applications.
 
 
Doesn't directly mention thickets
 
 
@article{rai2003engaging,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Engaging Facts and Policy: A Multi-Institutional Approach to Patent System Reform},
 
  author = {Rai, Arti K.},
 
  journal = {Columbia Law Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {103},
 
  number = {5},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Jun., 2003},
 
  pages = {pp. 1035-1135},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/1123832},
 
  ISSN = {00101958},
 
  abstract = {The Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, charged with adjudicating appeals in patent cases, has adopted an unusual approach that arrogates power over fact finding while it simultaneously invokes rule-formalism. Although the Federal Circuit's approach may be justified by the fact-finding and policy application deficiencies of the trial courts and the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO), it has had a negative impact on innovation policy and has resulted in a patent system that is sorely in need of reform. This Article argues that because of the interdependence of the various institutions within the patent system, reform of the system must be both multi-institutional and closely attentive to the institutional competence of the system's actors. Although Congress should clearly bolster the PTO's fact-finding abilities, giving plenary responsibility over factual questions to the PTO would not be cost effective. Accordingly, Congress should endow the system with improved fact-finding expertise through the institution of specialized trial courts. As for actual policy formulation, each of the available institutional options--the legislature, the PTO, and the courts--has substantial associated liabilities. On balance, however, the Federal Circuit is probably best positioned to formulate patent policy, so long as the fact-finding expertise of inferior institutions is bolstered and additional appellate mechanisms are instituted. By paying attention to institutional design and revising our institutions accordingly, we can achieve the patent system we should have had all along.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2003},
 
  publisher = {Columbia Law Review Association, Inc.},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2003 Columbia Law Review Association, Inc.},
 
  filename={Rai (2003) - Engaging Facts And Policy.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: patent reform
 
 
Defensive patenting has become particularly prominent in certain industries like
 
the semiconductor industry, where innovation is cumulative, and a thicket of relevant
 
patents often exists.
 
 
More?
 
over, the guidelines on utility incorporate, at least implicitly, economic
 
concerns that setting the utility standard too low could impede scientific
 
progress by creating a transaction-cost-heavy thicket of patents on basic
 
research.443
 
 
@inproceedings{regibeau2011assessment,
 
  title={Assessment of potential anticompetitive conduct in the field of intellectual property rights and assessment of the interplay between competition policy and IPR protection},
 
  author={Regibeau, Pierre and Rockett, Katharine},
 
  booktitle={Prepared for the European Commission, Publications Office of the European Union, ISBN 978-92-79-22210-8},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={Regibeau Rockett (2011) - Assessment Of Potential Anticompetitive Conduct.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy: Anticompetitive behaviour and patents - CORE PAPER. Solid Lit Review.
 
 
Over the last 10 years or so, there has been a growing policy concern about so-called patent
 
thickets. The terms “thicket” has been used somewhat indiscriminately in competition law
 
circles to describe various types of concentration of IPRs3. In this report, we use the term in
 
a much more specific and precise sense. Following Shapiro’s definition, patent thickets are
 
“an overlapping set of patent rights requiring that those seeking to commercialise new
 
technology obtain licenses from multiple partners”.4 Two conditions must then be fulfilled for
 
a thicket to arise. Firstly, the production and sale of a given product involves the use of a
 
large number of patent rights. Secondly, the ownership of those rights is dispersed.
 
 
4.Shapiro (2001), p. 119.
 
 
@article{reichman2007harmonization,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Harmonization without Consensus: Critical Reflections on Drafting a Substantive Patent Law Treaty},
 
  author = {Reichman, Jerome H. and Dreyfuss, Rochelle Cooper},
 
  journal = {Duke Law Journal},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {57},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Oct., 2007},
 
  pages = {pp. 85-130},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/40040588},
 
  ISSN = {00127086},
 
  abstract = {In this Article, we contend that the World Intellectual Property Organization's proposed Substantive Patent Law Treaty (SPLT) is premature. Developing countries are struggling to adjust to the heightened standards of intellectual property protection required by the TRIPS Agreement of 1994. With TRIPS, at least, these countries obtained side payments (in the form of trade concessions) to offset the rising costs of knowledge products. A free-standing instrument, such as the SPLT, would shrink the remaining flexibilities in the TRIPS Agreement with no side payments and no concessions to the catch-up strategies of developing countries at different stages of technological advancement. More controversially, we argue that a deep harmonization would boomerang against even its developed country promoters by creating more problems than it would solve. There is no vision of a properly functioning patent system for the developed world that commands even the appearance of a consensus. The evidence shows, instead, that the worldwide intellectual property system has entered a brave new scientific epoch, in which experts have only tentative, divergent ideas about how best to treat a daunting array of new technologies. The proposals for reconciling the needs of different sectors, such as information technology and biotechnology, pose hard, unresolved issues at a time when the costs of litigation are rising at the expense of profits from innovation. These difficulties are compounded by the tendency of universities to push patenting up stream, generating new rights to core methodologies and research tools. As new approaches to new technologies emerge in different jurisdictions, there is a need to gather empirical evidence to determine which, if any, of these still experimental solutions are preferable over time. Our argument need not foreclose other less intrusive options and measures surveyed in the Article that can reduce the costs of delaying harmonization. However, the international community should not rush to freeze legal obligations regarding the protection of intellectual property. It should wait until economists and policymakers better understand the dynamics of innovation and the role that patent rights play in promoting progress and until there are mechanisms in place to keep international obligations responsive to developments in science, technology, and the organization of the creative community.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2007},
 
  publisher = {Duke University School of Law},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2007 Duke University School of Law},
 
  filename={Reichman Dreyfuss (2007) - Harmonization Without Consensus.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: patent reform
 
 
For example, the risk of debilitating suits motivates participants to acquire multiple patents, hoping that with enough potential counterclaims, they can fend off or negotiate their way out of difficulty. The result is a vicious cycle: thickets of rights that are expensive (or nearly impossible) to clear, requiring an ever-larger arsenal of defensive protection
 
 
 
@article{reitzig2004private,
 
  title={The private values of ‘thickets’ and ‘fences’: towards an updated picture of the use of patents across industries},
 
  author={Reitzig, M.},
 
  journal={Economics of Innovation and New Technology},
 
  volume={13},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={457--476},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={Taylor \& Francis},
 
  filename={Reitzig (2004) - The Private Values Of Thickets And Fences.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Thickets different in discrete vs. complex tech. CORE PAPER.
 
 
On the basis of a novel data set of 612 European patents and related inventions from five different industries, it is shown
 
that multiple patents per invention are filed in both discrete and complex technologies. Multivariate analysis of the data
 
suggests that in selected discrete technologies, patent ‘fences’ may serve to exclude competitors whereas in complex
 
technologies, ‘thickets’ represent exchange forums for complementary technology. The results expand on traditional
 
views of profitable patent exploitation across industries and elaborate on the most recent findings by Cohen et al.
 
(Cohen, W.M., Nelson, R.R. and Walsh, J.P. (2000) Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions
 
and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (or not). Cambridge, MA: NBER.) The analysis suggests that different
 
legislative issues arise from multiple patenting per innovation in complex and discrete technologies depending on
 
the degree of technological complementarity. The results have unexpected policy implications in that they illustrate
 
how patentees could eliminate competition in the form of substitute technologies through fencing. They have wide
 
managerial implications regarding the valuation of patent portfolios and the design of corporate IP strategies.
 
 
@article{reitzig2007sharks,
 
  title={On sharks, trolls, and their patent prey—Unrealistic damage awards and firms’ strategies of “being infringed”},
 
  author={Reitzig, M. and Henkel, J. and Heath, C.},
 
  journal={Research Policy},
 
  volume={36},
 
  number={1},
 
  pages={134--154},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Reitzig Henkel Heath (2007) - On Sharks Trolls And Their Patent Prey.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Trolls
 
 
As both
 
articles show, the “strategic use” of patents (the two most important
 
types being blocking and cross-licensing with patent ‘thickets’ playing
 
a major role for the latter), has classically been discussed from the perspective
 
of those patent holders who either engage in the production
 
of their own technological goods or consider themselves professional
 
intellectual property suppliers who repeatedly interact with manufacturers.
 
The strategy of “being infringed” as pursued by trolls is a
 
different phenomenon. While not entirely new(see Section 4.1, quoting
 
Lemelson versus Mattel), the broad systematic use of troll strategies
 
appears to be very recent, however.
 
 
@article{rey2012abuse,
 
  title={Abuse of dominance and licensing of intellectual property},
 
  author={Rey, P. and Salant, D.},
 
  journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization},
 
  year={2012},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Rey Salant (2012) - Abuse Of Dominance And Licensing Of Intellectual Property.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Underlying theory of thickets
 
 
Patent thickets, layers of licenses a �rm needs to be able to o�er products that embody
 
technologies owned by multiple �rms, and licensing policies have drawn increasing
 
scrutiny from policy makers. Patent thickets involve complementary products, which
 
gives rise to double marginalization { the so-called royalty stacking problem { and has
 
the potential to retard di�usion of new technologies and reduce consumer welfare.1
 
 
One is the patent thicket problem,
 
which is an extension of Cournot's 1838 complementary product oligopoly model to
 
IP.5 When there are two or more owners of essential IP, each fails to take into account
 
the impact of its licensing policy on the owners of complementary IP; this results in
 
double-marginalization
 
 
Patent thickets have long been a concern due to the potential for delaying deployment
 
of products and adversely a�ecting consumers. To examine the implications of such
 
patent thickets, we consider a model in which the upstream IP owner or owners sell
 
into a market in which there are di�erentiated products and positive �xed entry costs.
 
It is well known that, in the absence of vertical licensing agreements, there can be
 
excessive entry, due to business stealing e�ects, or insu�cient entry, if �rms entering
 
the market appropriate only part of the surplus they generate. We revisit this issue,
 
taking into account the upstream owner(s)' licensing policy
 
 
@inproceedings{rubinfeld2004strategic,
 
  title={The strategic use of patents: Implications for antitrust},
 
  author={Rubinfeld, D.L. and Maness, R.},
 
  booktitle={Antitrust, Patent and Copyright Conference},
 
  year={2004},
 
  filename={Rubinfeld Maness (2004) - The Strategic Use Of Patents Implications For Antitrust.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Creating a thicket to raise rivals cost
 
 
To see more specifically how a firm could use a large patent portfolio to raise rivals’
 
costs, consider the case of a differentiated product oligopoly where innovation and product
 
design are important elements of competition among rivals. In this case, a firm with a large
 
patent portfolio surrounding competitors’ key technologies (i.e., a “patent thicket”) has the
 
opportunity to use its patent portfolio to lessen competition in the final goods market.17
 
 
@article{sabety2004nanotechnology,
 
  title={Nanotechnology innovation and the patent thicket: Which IP policies promote growth},
 
  author={Sabety, T.},
 
  journal={Alb. LJ Sci. \& Tech.},
 
  volume={15},
 
  pages={477},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Sabety (2004) - Nanotechnology Innovation And The Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Thickets in nanotech (comparison with radio industry)
 
 
Yet, several commentators have raised concerns
 
that the extraordinary pace of patenting of nanotechnology5
 
will result in a patent deadlock6 that will stifle innovation and
 
impede economic growth.7
 
 
@article{santore2010patent,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Patent Pools as a Solution to Efficient Licensing of Complementary Patents? Some Experimental Evidence},
 
  author = {Rudy Santore and Michael McKee, and David Bjornstad},
 
  journal = {Journal of Law and Economics},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {53},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {February 2010},
 
  pages = {pp. 167-183},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/600078},
 
  ISSN = {00222186},
 
  abstract = {Abstract Production requiring licensing groups of complementary patents implements a coordination game among patent holders, who can price patents by choosing among combinations of fixed and royalty fees. Summed across patents, these fees become the total producer cost of the package of patents. Royalties, because they function as excise taxes, add to marginal costs, resulting in higher prices and reduced quantities of the downstream product and lower payoffs to the patent holders. Using fixed fees eliminates this inefficiency but yields a more complex coordination game in which there are multiple equilibria, which are very fragile in that small mistakes can lead the downstream firm to not license the technology, resulting in inefficient outcomes. We report on a laboratory market investigation of the efficiency effects of coordinated pricing of patents in a patent pool. We find that pool-like pricing agreements can yield fewer coordination failures in the pricing of complementary patents.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2010},
 
  publisher = {The University of Chicago Press for The Booth School of Business of the University of Chicago and The University of Chicago Law School},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2010 The University of Chicago},
 
  filename={Santore McKee Bjornstad (2010) - Patent Pools As A Solution To Efficient Licensing Of Complementary Patents.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Econ: Theory with Empircs: patent pools
 
 
More recently, a National Academy of Sciences (2006) committee studied the issue,
 
concluding that even though evidence of blocking or market failures has yet to emerge, the anticommons
 
or patent thickets may well emerge as profit opportunities in biomedical markets grow
 
 
Shapiro (2001) broadens the concept as a “patent thicket” in
 
which possible outcomes include excessively high fees for the use of the patent set, uncertainty
 
regarding potential patent infringement, and, in the limit, holdup problems.
 
 
@article{sanyal2005peanut,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Peanut Butter Patents versus the New Economy: Does the Increased Rate of Patenting Signal More Invention or Just Lower Standards?},
 
  Author = {Sanyal, Paroma And Jaffe, Adam B. And Sanyal, Panoma},
 
  journal = {Annals of Economics and Statistics / Annales d'Économie et de Statistique},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {Contributions in memory of Zvi Griliches},
 
  volume = {},
 
  number = {79/80},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {JULY/DECEMBER 2005},
 
  pages = {pp. 211-240},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/20777576},
 
  ISSN = {0769489X},
 
  abstract = {The explosion in the patenting rate in the U.S. during the last half of the 1990s is often attributed partly to an apparent decline in examination standards. We estimate a simultaneous equation model accounting for the fact that a decline in examination standards would itself induce an increase in dubious applications. We have a multi-dimensional panel, with data on the application and grant rates and country of origin and destination. We find that a 'loosening' of the grants standard by 1 percent increases applications by 8 percent in the full sample and by 3 percent in the Non-US sample. After accounting for the endogenous application response, the application elasticity of grants is around 0.124 for the full sample and 0.145 for the Non-US one. Countries whose patent applications are more likely to be successful in the US are more likely to be successful in other countries as well. These findings confirm that inventors respond to increased likelihood of success at the patent office by filing more applications, but also confirm earlier findings that the surge in patenting in the US in the last two decades appears to be driven to a significant extent by an increase in the underlying invention rate. L'explosion du taux de délivrance de brevets aux Etats-Unis durant la seconde moitié des années 90 est souvent attribuée en partie à un relâchement des niveaux d'exigence requis à l'examen des inventions. Nous estimons un modèle d'équations simultanées rendant compte du fait qu'un abaissement du niveau d'exigence devrait induire une augmentation des demandes douteuses. Nous utilisons un panel multi-dimensionnel, contenant des données sur la nature des demandes de brevet, les taux de délivrance, les pays d'origine et de destination. Nous trouvons qu'une diminution du niveau d'exigence pour la délivrance des brevets de 1% augmente le nombre de demandes de 8% dans l'échantillon total et de 3% dans l'échantillon non-US. En tenant compte de l'endogénéité.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2005},
 
  publisher = {L'INSEE / GENES on behalf of ADRES},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2005 L'INSEE / GENES},
 
  filename={Sanyal Jaffe Sanyal (2005) - Peanut Butter Patents Versus The New Economy.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: looser standards dramatically increase patenting
 
 
ABSTRACT. - The explosion in the patenting rate in the U.S. during the last half of the 1990s is often attributed partly to an apparent decline in examination standards. We estimate a simultaneous equation model accounting for the fact that a decline in examination standards would itself induce an increase in dubious applications. We have a multi-dimensional panel, with data on the application and grant rates and country of origin and destination. We find that a loosening' of the grants standard by 1 percent increases applications by 8 percent in the full sample and by 3 percent in the Non-US sample. After accounting for the endogenous application response, the application elasticity of grants is around 0.124 for the full sample and 0.145 for the Non-US one. Countries whose patent applications are more likely to be successful in the US are more likely to be successful in other countries as well. These findings confirm that inventors respond to increased likelihood of success at the patent office by filing more applications, but also confirm earlier findings that the surge in patenting in the US in the last two decades appears to be driven to a significant extent by an increase in the underlying invention rate.
 
 
@book{schacht2006patent,
 
  title={Patent reform: Issues in the biomedical and software industries},
 
  author={Schacht, W.H.},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Congressional Research Service (7 April 2006), available at:< http://sharp. sefora. org/wp-content/uploads/2007/12/rl33367. pdf},
 
  filename={Schacht (2006) - Patent Reform Issues In The Biomedical And Software Industries.pdf}
 
}
 
 
PolicyReport: Patent reform (rpt for congress)
 
 
Concerns have been expressed in the academic community that the propensity
 
to patent and the extensive use of cross licensing has resulted in a “patent thicket”
 
where ownership of patent title is used to block others from innovating. According
 
to Bessen and Hunt, “This may have increased the attractiveness of a strategy that
 
emphasizes patent rights over a strategy based on R&D.”61 However, other experts
 
maintain that this might not be a true assessment of the situation. In an article for the
 
Virginia Journal of Law and Technology, David Evans and Anne Layne-Farrar argue
 
it is not clear that a patent thicket exists. “Other industries with longstanding histories
 
of patenting could be categorized as having cumulative and sequential R&D, yet they
 
do not display signs of innovation gridlock.”62 There are additional ways to prevent
 
the use of patents to block innovation including the use of pro-competitive patent
 
pools and antitrust enforcement.
 
 
@article{scheffman2003twenty,
 
  title={Twenty years of raising rivals' costs: History, assessment, and future},
 
  author={Scheffman, D.T. and Higgins, R.S.},
 
  journal={Geo. Mason L. Rev.},
 
  volume={12},
 
  pages={371},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Scheffman Higgins (2003) - Twenty Years Of Raising Rivals Costs History Assessment And Future.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Raising rival's cost
 
 
More difficult to reach are what appear to be anti-consumer (but may
 
be more difficult to reach as anticompetitive) activities by “patent vultures,”
 
and the use of patent thickets (sometimes combined with high stakes
 
(for the defendant) actions at the International Trade Commission)
 
 
 
@article{schmalensee2009standard,
 
  title={Standard-Setting, Innovation Specialists And Competition Policy},
 
  author={Schmalensee, R.},
 
  journal={The Journal of Industrial Economics},
 
  volume={57},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={526--552},
 
  year={2009},
 
  publisher={Wiley Online Library},
 
  filename={Schmalensee (2009) - Standard Setting Innovation Specialists And Competition Policy.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Standard setting
 
 
To the extent that patent policy inflates the number of patents that must be licensed in order to practice a standard, it contributes to what has beecalled a ‘patent thicket’ through which standard-setting must pass. This clearly complicates
 
3
 
standard-setting and may make standards less socially valuable.10 As my concern here is with antitrust policy, however, I will treat patent policy as given.
 
 
One might argue that the rate of innovation or at least of patenting is in fact too high in some sectors, particularly those in which the patent thicket problem is severe. A problem 26
 
with this argument is that the returns to major innovations would be reduced by collective negotiation, not just the returns to the minor advances that contribute more to patent thickets than to real progress. Alternatively, one could contend that in many industries the probability that any given innovation will be involved in standard-setting is low enough that the general use of collective negotiation in standard-setting would not have a major impact on the expected returns to innovation. This argument does not seem persuasive in the IT/communications sector, however, where standard-setting is of central importance.
 
 
@article{schmidt2007negotiating,
 
  title={Negotiating the RNAi patent thicket},
 
  author={Schmidt, C.},
 
  journal={Nature biotechnology},
 
  volume={25},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={273--280},
 
  year={2007},
 
  publisher={New York, NY: Nature Pub. Co., 1996-},
 
  filename={Schmidt (2007) - Negotiating The Rnai Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: Thicket due to a single firm in RNA interference?
 
 
Currently based in San Francisco, Sirna spent
 
its recent past accumulating one of the broadest
 
RNAi patent estates in existence. Merck now
 
owns that estate, and all the uncertainty that
 
comes with it. As a Nobel-prize winning technology,
 
RNAi could become biotech’s third act,
 
after gene cloning and monoclonal antibodies.
 
But no one can say whether it will ever bring
 
useful drugs to market.
 
 
@article{schmidt2008complementary,
 
  title={Complementary Patents and Market Structure},
 
  author={Schmidt, K.},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP7005},
 
  filename={Schmidt (2008) - Complementary Patents And Market Structure.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of complementary patent problems
 
 
Thus, if a downstream firm wants to produce goods that are based
 
on the standard it requires access to each of the essential patents. All the patents are perfect
 
complements. Therefore each of the upstream IP holders has monopoly power over the
 
downstream market. This “patent thicket” (Shapiro, 2001) gives rise to a complements
 
problem: each patent holder does not internalize the negative external effect on the revenues
 
of the other patent holders when setting his royalties, so the sum of all royalties will be
 
inefficiently high. In addition, there is a vertical double marginalization problem if firms on
 
the downstream market have market power. These externalities affect not only the prices
 
charged downstream, they also affect the incentives to enter the downstream market with new
 
product varieties and to develop new technology that improves the quality of the standard.
 
 
@article{schneider2008fences,
 
  title={Fences and competition in patent races},
 
  author={Schneider, C.},
 
  journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization},
 
  volume={26},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={1348--1364},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Schneider (2008) - Fences And Competition In Patent Races.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Fencing with substitutes
 
 
This paper studies the behaviour of ?rms facing the decision to cre-
 
ate a patent fence, de?ned as a portfolio of substitute patents. We set
 
up a patent race model, where ?rms can decide either to patent their
 
inventions, or to rely on secrecy. It is shown that ?rms build patent
 
fences, when the duopoly pro?ts net of R&D costs are positive. We
 
also demonstrate that in this context, a ?rm will rely on secrecy when
 
the speed of discovery of the subsequent invention is high compared
 
to the competitor?s. Furthermore, we compare the model under the
 
First-to-Invent and First-to-File legal rules. Finally, we analyze the
 
welfare implications of patent fences.
 
 
However, ?rms patent for di¤erent reasons in ?discrete? product
 
industries, in which an invention can be protected by a limited number of
 
patents and in ?complex?product industries, where a single patent is not
 
enough to protect an invention. More precisely, ?rms will patent a coherent
 
group of inventions, which form what is sometimes called a patent "bulk",
 
aimed at protecting one product. The "bulk" can either be a "fence" of
 
substitute patents or a "thicket" of complementary patents (see Reitzig, 2004
 
and Cohen et al., 2000).
 
 
While the issue of "thickets" of complementary technologies in cumula-
 
tive innovations has been extensively analyzed2, as well as the institutional
 
solutions to overcome this problem (Lerner and Tirole, 2005 and Shapiro,
 
2001), little attention has been paid to fencing patents so far.
 
 
@article{shand2007trends,
 
  title={Trends in intellectual property and nanotechnology: implications for the global south},
 
  author={Shand, H. and Wetter, K.J.},
 
  journal={Journal of Intellectual Property Rights},
 
  volume={12},
 
  pages={111--117},
 
  year={2007},
 
  filename={Shand Wetter (2007) - Trends In Intellectual Property And Nanotechnology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: nanotech
 
 
Not copyable. Not good either - no support for argument that there is a thicket and it is a problem.
 
 
 
@article{sharrott2006intellectual,
 
  title={Intellectual Property Developments in Biochip Nanotechology},
 
  author={Sharrott, D. and Sayeed, H.A.},
 
  journal={Nanotech. L. \& Bus.},
 
  volume={3},
 
  pages={20},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Sharrott Sayeed (2006) - Intellectual Property Developments In Biochip Nanotechology.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: thicket in DNA microarrays (some nanotech genetic thingies)
 
 
When the
 
National Institutes of Health applied for the first EST patents in 1991, the possibility arose that such
 
patents could overlap with and possibly invalidate later patents directed toward fully-sequenced,
 
expressed genes.8 Commentators describe this proliferation of overlapping patents as a potential “patent
 
thicket”—a tangle of intellectual property rights through which companies must cut to bring new
 
technologies to market.9 In the thicket, scientists and corporations might be forced to renegotiate
 
constantly for the right to exercise any individual gene patent, or to use commercial products obtained
 
from that gene.
 
 
Until recently, the most significant IP concern about biochips involved the patentability of expressed
 
sequence tags
 
 
On September 7, 2005, the Federal Circuit signaled its agreement with the PTO guidelines by
 
holding that ESTs are unpatentable because of a lack of specific and substantial utility.13 In re Fisher
 
involved an appeal from the Board of Patent Appeals and Interferences for an invention relating to ESTs
 
purified from maize plants. The Federal Circuit held that, absent clear identification of the related maize
 
plant genes, the claimed ESTs were not “researched and understood to the point of providing an
 
immediate, well-defined, real world benefit to the public meriting the grant of a patent.”14 The Court
 
majority was unmoved by the argument that ESTs could offer substantial utility as laboratory research
 
tools.15
 
In re Fisher marks a paradigm shift in biotechnology innovation. The Federal Circuit appears intent
 
on preventing patent thickets from taking root in genetic applications. How In re Fisher will affect
 
business growth and research and development in the microfluidics industry will be of intense interest to
 
investors in the coming months and years.
 
 
@article{serafino2007survey,
 
  title={Survey of patent pools demonstrates variety of purposes and management structures},
 
  author={Serafino, D.},
 
  journal={Knowledge Ecology International. http://keionline. org/content/view/69/1},
 
  year={2007},
 
  filename={Serafino (2007) - Survey Of Patent Pools Demonstrates Variety Of Purposes And Management Structures.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory and Empirics: Licensing to resolve the thicket
 
 
In some high technology industries the process of research and development is comparable to
 
the continuous extension of a pyramid through the addition of new building blocks at the top
 
[Shapiro (2001)]. Here, the pyramid serves as a metaphor for the cumulativeness of scientific
 
research in complex product industries.1
 
Firms increasingly protect their contributions to this pyramid with patents. As a result
 
several high technology industries are now affected by a “patent thicket” [Heller and Eisenberg
 
(1998); Hall and Ziedonis (2001); Shapiro (2001)]. In a patent thicket many rival firms hold
 
patents protecting components of a single technology. Whenever a firm uses such a technology
 
it is vulnerable to hold up by firms holding blocking patents [Grindley and Teece (1997),
 
Jaffe (2000), Shapiro (2001)]. The threat posed by blocking patents frequently induces firms
 
to build up a large portfolio of patents. This creates a strong bargaining position for the firm
 
owning the portfolio in any disputes with rivals. In a patent thicket all firms face the prospect
 
of hold up and have strong incentives to patent, which perpetuates the patent thicket. Hold
 
up in a patent thicket may be resolved through licensing of blocking patents. Therefore, an
 
understanding of how licensing works in industries affected by patent thickets is increasingly
 
important.
 
 
@incollection{shapiro2001navigating,
 
  title={Navigating the patent thicket: Cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting},
 
  author={Shapiro, C.},
 
  booktitle={Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 1},
 
  pages={119--150},
 
  year={2001},
 
  publisher={MIT Press},
 
  filename={Shapiro (2001) - Navigating The Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
CORE PAPER!!!
 
 
REVIEW IT CAREFULLY (AGAIN)
 
 
@article{shapiro2003antitrust,
 
  title={Antitrust limits to patent settlements},
 
  author={Shapiro, C.},
 
  journal={RAND Journal of Economics},
 
  pages={391--411},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Shapiro (2003) - Antitrust Limits To Patent Settlements.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Patents, patent litigation, and patent settlements increasingly influence competition. Settlements
 
ofpatent disputesc ome in manyforms,i ncludingl icensing and cross-licensinga greementsp, atent
 
pools, mergers, and joint ventures. While frequently procompetitive, such settlements can stifle
 
competition and harm consumers. I propose a specific antitrust rule limiting such settlements: a
 
settlement must leave consumers at least as well off as they would have been from ongoing patent
 
litigation. After establishing that profitable settlements satisfying this constraint generally exist,
 
I show how this antitrust rule can be used to evaluate three types of settlements: mergers, patent
 
pools, and negotiated entry dates.
 
 
Making matters even more complex, many products can potentially infringe multiple patents. As
 
described in Shapiro (2001), more and more companies are facing a patent thicket requiring them
 
to obtain multiple licenses to bring their products safely to market.
 
 
 
@article{siebert2006jostling,
 
  title={Jostling for advantage: Licensing and entry into patent portfolio races},
 
  author={Siebert, R. and Von Graevenitz, G.},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={CEPR Discussion Paper},
 
  filename={Siebert VonGraevenitz (2006) - Jostling For Advantage Licensing And Entry Into Patent Portfolio Races.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Licensing and entry in a thicket CORE PAPER
 
 
Licensing in a patent thicket allows firms to either avoid or resolve hold-up. Firms’ R&D
 
incentives depend on whether they license ex ante or ex post. We develop a model of a
 
patent portfolio race, which allows for endogenous R&D efforts, to study firms’ choice
 
between ex ante and ex post licensing. The model shows that firms’ relationships in product
 
markets and technology space jointly determine the type of licensing contract chosen.
 
In particular, product market competitors are more likely to avoid patent portfolio races,
 
since the threat of hold-up increases. On the other hand, more valuable technologies are
 
more likely to give rise to patent portfolio races. We also discuss the welfare implications
 
of these results.
 
 
Rival firms, in complex product industries, are often owners of complementary assets.1 Therefore,
 
firms in these industries are more frequently forced to license technologies from each
 
other than rival firms in other industries. Increasingly, rival firms in complex product industries
 
protect these component technologies with patents [Hall (2004)]. It is, therefore, likely
 
that ownership of technologies underlying a complex product is highly dispersed and a “patent
 
thicket” emerges [Heller and Eisenberg (1998); Hall and Ziedonis (2001); Shapiro (2001)].
 
Firms caught in a patent thicket must cooperate by licensing technologies, otherwise mutual
 
blocking of technological improvements is likely and competition degenerates into litigation.
 
 
@article{siebert2008does,
 
  title={Does Licensing Resolve Hold Up in the Patent Thicket?},
 
  author={Siebert, R. and Graevenitz, G.},
 
  year={2008},
 
  filename={Siebert Graevenitz (2008) - Does Licensing Resolve Hold Up In The Patent Thicket.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Empirical: Licensing and thickets CORE PAPER
 
 
In a patent thicket licensing provides a mechanism to either avoid or resolve hold up.
 
We study the choice between ex ante licensing to avoid hold up and ex post licensing
 
to resolve it. Firms’ choice of licensing contract is studied in the context of a patent
 
portfolio race. We show that high expected blocking leads to ex ante licensing while ex
 
post licensing arises if expected blocking is low but realized blocking is high. Also, ex
 
ante licensing reduces firms’ R&D incentives. A sample selection model of licensing is
 
derived from the theoretical model. In this framework theoretical predictions on effects
 
of blocking are tested with data from the semiconductor industry. We show that licensing
 
helps firms to resolve blocking. However, licensing is not a cure all: it decreases as
 
fragmentation of property rights increases and arises mainly between large firms with
 
similar market shares. Using a treatment effects model we also confirm the prediction
 
that ex ante licensing reduces the level of R&D investment.
 
 
Firms increasingly protect their contributions to this pyramid with patents. As a result
 
several high technology industries are now affected by a “patent thicket” [Heller and Eisenberg
 
(1998); Hall and Ziedonis (2001); Shapiro (2001)]. In a patent thicket many rival firms hold
 
patents protecting components of a single technology. Whenever a firm uses such a technology
 
it is vulnerable to hold up by firms holding blocking patents [Grindley and Teece (1997),
 
Jaffe (2000), Shapiro (2001)]. The threat posed by blocking patents frequently induces firms
 
to build up a large portfolio of patents. This creates a strong bargaining position for the firm
 
owning the portfolio in any disputes with rivals. In a patent thicket all firms face the prospect
 
of hold up and have strong incentives to patent, which perpetuates the patent thicket. Hold
 
up in a patent thicket may be resolved through licensing of blocking patents. Therefore, an
 
understanding of how licensing works in industries affected by patent thickets is increasingly
 
important.
 
 
Our results indicate that licensing in the semiconductor industry is undertaken primarily
 
by larger and more symmetric pairs of firms. We show that licensing choices made by such
 
firms is consistent with a model of patent portfolio races in which licensing guarantees freedom
 
to operate. This contrasts with existing models of licensing which focus on technology
 
35
 
exchange and or attempts to affect the intensity of product market competition [Scotchmer
 
(2004), Shapiro (2003a)]. We also show that licensing ex ante, before R&D investments are
 
made allows firms to reduce the levels of patenting. This finding further supports the patent
 
portfolio race model of patenting in the semiconductor industry.
 
 
Finally, we find that the fragmentation
 
of patent rights reduces firms’ propensity to license ex ante and ex post. Thus a deepening of
 
36
 
patent thickets resulting from more complex blocking relationships seems to undermine the
 
usefulness of licensing to resolve blocking.
 
 
Worryingly our results also indicate that licensing becomes less important as patent
 
ownership becomes more fragmented.
 
 
@article{siebert2010licensing,
 
  title={Licensing in the Patent Thicket-Timing and Benefits},
 
  author={Siebert, R.B. and Von Graevenitz, G.},
 
  year={2010},
 
  filename={Siebert VonGraevenitz (2010) - Licensing In The Patent Thicket Timing And Benefits.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory and empirics: licensing in thickets
 
 
CORE PAPER. Seems a combination of two of the above.
 
 
Licensing can be a solution for hold-up in patent thickets. In this paper we study whether
 
licensing is an effective solution for hold-up. To do this we distinguish between ex ante
 
and ex post licensing. A theoretical model shows that firms’ expectations of blocking in
 
a patent thicket determine whether they license ex ante while ex post licensing arises if
 
expected blocking was low but realized blocking turns out to be high. It can also be shown
 
that ex ante licensing will allow firms to reduce their patenting efforts. A sample selection
 
model of licensing is derived from the theoretical model. Applying this to data from the
 
semiconductor industry we show that licensing does help firms to resolve blocking. However,
 
the probability of observing licensing decreases as fragmentation of property rights
 
increases and arises mainly between large firms with similar market shares. Licensing
 
experience is also an important determinant of licensing. As expected ex ante licensing
 
allows firms to reduce the level of patenting.
 
 
In a patent thicket many firms hold patents protecting components of a single technology.
 
Whenever a firm uses such a technology it is vulnerable to hold-up by firms holding blocking
 
patents (Grindley and Teece, 1997; Shapiro, 2001). The threat posed by blocking patents
 
frequently induces firms to build large patent portfolios in costly patent portfolio races. These
 
bolster firms’ bargaining positions in disputes with rivals (Grindley and Teece, 1997; Lemley,
 
2001). Patent thickets undermine the proper functioning of patent systems: they raise costs of
 
using complex technology and increase incentives to acquire marginal patents.
 
 
These results imply that licensing has important benefits for large firms in the semiconductor
 
industry. Ex ante licensing reduces competitive pressure and the intensity of patent
 
portfolio races if firms expect blocking to be high. As the theoretical model indicates, these
 
are precisely the settings in which the pressure to patent is greatest. Ex post licensing allows
 
firms at least to exchange blocking patents in settings in which patent portfolio races are less
 
intense. Our results show clearly that ability to license is an acquired skill that helps firms
 
regulate the intensity of competition for patents. This is especially true for ex ante licensing.
 
Worryingly, our results also indicate that licensing becomes less important as patent ownership
 
becomes more fragmented.
 
 
@article{siebert2010jostling,
 
  title={Jostling for advantage or not: Choosing between patent portfolio races and ex ante licensing},
 
  author={Siebert, R. and Von Graevenitz, G.},
 
  journal={Journal of economic behavior \& organization},
 
  volume={73},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={225--245},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Siebert VonGraevenitz (2010) - Jostling For Advantage Or Not.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory and empirics: licensing in thickets
 
 
CORE PAPER. Seems a combination of two of the above.
 
 
Complex high technology industries are increasingly affected by patent thickets in which
 
firms’ patents mutually block the use of important technologies. Firms facing patent thickets
 
patent intensively to acquire bargaining chips and use licensing to ensure freedom
 
to operate. Such licensing allows rivals to either avoid or resolve hold-up from blocking
 
patents. R&D incentives depend on whether licensing takes place ex ante or ex post. We
 
model the choice between ex ante licensing and entry into patent portfolio races leading to
 
ex post licensing. It is shown that higher degrees of blocking lead firms to license ex post,
 
while stronger product market competition leads firms to license ex ante. Empirical results
 
support these theoretical predictions.
 
 
A patent thicket consists of complementary patents related to one technology. The patents in a patent
 
thicket belong to many rival firms. In the absence of cross-licensing agreements, or patent pools, use of the technology is
 
blocked.
 
 
@article{somaya2003strategic,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Strategic Determinants of Decisions Not to Settle Patent Litigation},
 
  author = {Somaya, Deepak},
 
  journal = {Strategic Management Journal},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {24},
 
  number = {1},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {Jan., 2003},
 
  pages = {pp. 17-38},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/20060509},
 
  ISSN = {01432095},
 
  abstract = {Settlement outcomes in patent litigation are modeled as resulting from strategies pursued by firms with their patented technologies. Hypotheses are derived for two types of influences: the use of patents as isolating mechanisms to protect valuable strategic stakes, and their 'defensive' role in obtaining access to external technologies through mutual hold-up. Parameter estimates from a sample selection probit model provide support for the strategic stakes hypotheses, while the evidence for mutual hold-up is inconclusive. Interindustry comparisons show that nonsettlement of patent suits in both research medicines and computers is increased by strategic stakes and, in addition, mutual hold-up appears to play an important role in computer patent suits.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2003},
 
  publisher = {Wiley},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2003 Wiley},
 
  filename={Somaya (2003) - Strategic Determinants Of Decisions Not To Settle Patent Litigation.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ/Mgmt: ICT and Biotech: When to settle suits
 
 
Settlement outcomes in patent litigation are modeled as resulting from strategies pursued by firms
 
with their patented technologies. Hypotheses are derived for two types of influences: the use of
 
patents as isolating mechanisms to protect valuable strategic stakes, and their 'defensive
 
'role
 
in obtaining access to external technologies through mutual hold-up. Parameter estimates from
 
a sample selection probit model provide support for the strategic stakes hypotheses, while the
 
evidence for mutual hold-up is inconclusive. Interindustry comparisons show that nonsettlement
 
of patent suits in both research medicines and computers is increased by strategic stakes and, in
 
addition, mutual hold-up appears to play an important role in computer patent suits. Copyright
 
 
Computer suits are much more likely to
 
include more than one patent, consistent with
 
the perception that individual computer patents
 
are much less effective at blocking rivals (Cohen
 
et al., 2000), and that thickets of patents may
 
be required instead. Patent challenges (suits filed
 
by the nonpatentee) are somewhat more common
 
in research medicines, but the difference is
 
not significant. Consistent with the settlement
 
inducing role of mutual hold-up in systems
 
product industries (Hypothesis 4b), computer
 
suits in the sample are more likely (8%) than
 
research medicine suits (1.5%) to be a part of
 
counter-suits between rivals in litigation.10
 
 
When strong,
 
watertight patents are available, as in pharma
 
ceuticals, firms may be able to rely on them
 
to isolate key commercial opportunities (Merges,
 
1998). On the other hand, in systems products
 
industries, thickets of patents may be necessary
 
to foil attempts to invent around the patent, and
 
obtain a robust patent position. Moreover, defen
 
sive patenting?the building of large patent port
 
folios?may become necessary if rivals, aided by a
 
strong enforcement regime, are able to effectively
 
threaten to hold up a firm's commercial operations
 
(Hall and Ziedonis, 2001).
 
 
@article{somaya2011innovation,
 
  title={Innovation in Multi-Invention Contexts: Mapping Solutions to Technological and Intellectual Property Complexity},
 
  author={Somaya, D. and Teece, D. and Wakeman, S.},
 
  journal={California Management Review},
 
  volume={53},
 
  number={4},
 
  pages={47--79},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={JSTOR},
 
  filename={Somaya Teece Wakeman (2011) - Innovation In Multi Invention Contexts.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Mgmt: Firm Strategy in response to thickets etc.
 
 
Scholars such as Michael Heller and Rebecca Eisenberg, Carl
 
Shapiro, and others have drawn attention—arguably too much attention—to
 
the transactional problems created for innovators by such dispersed ownership
 
and the density (or so-called thickets) of patents.58 Less attention has been paid
 
by those authors to the equally important role of patents for supporting innovation
 
in multi-invention settings. Innovators and entrepreneurs are often among
 
the most enthusiastic supporters of the patent system because they perceive it as
 
providing safeguards from misappropriation of their inventions.59 Research has
 
also shown that innovators are often able to devise “working solutions” to navigate
 
patent access concerns, and that patents may in turn be crucial for enabling
 
transactions in technology.60
 
 
@article{sternitzke2008visualizing,
 
  title={Visualizing patent statistics by means of social network analysis tools},
 
  author={Sternitzke, C. and Bartkowski, A. and Schramm, R.},
 
  journal={World Patent Information},
 
  volume={30},
 
  number={2},
 
  pages={115--131},
 
  year={2008},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Sternitzke Bartkowski Schramm (2008) - Visualizing Patent Statistics By Means Of Social Network Analysis Tools.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Networks: CORE PAPER
 
 
The present paper reviews the literature on social network analysis with applications to bibliometric data, and in particular, patent
 
information. Several approaches of network analysis are conducted in the field of optoelectronics to exemplify the power of network
 
analysis tools. Cooperation networks between inventors and applicants are illustrated, emphasizing bibliometric measures such as activity,
 
citation frequency, etc. as well as network theoretical measures, e.g. centrality or betweenness. In this context it is found that inventors
 
who serve as interfaces or links between different inventor groups apply for technologically broader patents, hence, benefiting from
 
their access to different knowledge through their position. Furthermore, citation networks of patent documents as well as patent applicants
 
were drawn. Here, patent thickets could be identified. The position of applicants within citation networks seems to be useful in
 
explaining behaviour of the applicants in the marketplace, such as cooperation or patent infringement trials.
 
 
On the second level, key patents, characterized by a high
 
citation frequency within a network, and their relationship
 
to other patents can be identified more easily. It was
 
showed that such analyses can be deployed to identify patent
 
thickets [9]. When inventors or patent applicants are
 
considered as nodes within a network, it can be demonstrated
 
to what extent they build upon each others knowledge.
 
Closeness between two nodes in a network signifies
 
that they are technologically related. If, for instance, two
 
applicants are situated closely together, and they do not
 
cooperate, then they should be engaged in a high level of
 
technological competition. However, if they cooperate,
 
then it seems rather that they jointly develop new technology,
 
using complementary competencies. To calculate the
 
citation ties between applicants to better assess technological
 
competitiveness between these players, two approaches
 
are chosen:
 
(i) Simple counts, i.e. if applicant A cited six patent families
 
from applicant B, then six citations are counted.
 
(ii) Multiple citation counts, i.e. if applicant A cited six
 
patent families from applicant B, but if each patent
 
family was cited twice (e.g. from two different patent
 
families of applicant A) then twelve citations are
 
counted. This approach should deliver more exact
 
results than the former.
 
 
@article{strandburg2006law,
 
  title={Law and the Science of Networks: An Overview and an Application to the ``Patent Explosion"},
 
  author={Strandburg, K.J.},
 
  journal={bepress Legal Series},
 
  pages={1617},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={bepress},
 
  filename={Strandburg (2006) - Law And The Science Of Networks.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law/Econ: Citations measures description (good). CORE PAPER, also useful for OTHER research
 
 
At the same time, developments in the law, including the establishment of a
 
single appellate court -- the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals -- to hear the vast majority
 
of patent appeals in the United States, have led to debate as to whether the legal system is
 
becoming increasingly “patent-friendly;” whether patents are being issued for lower
 
quality innovations; and whether the legal rights awarded to patentees are becoming
 
stronger.52
 
 
There are dire predictions of a patent “thicket,”65 in
 
which technological progress is made increasingly difficult by the need to negotiate
 
multiple levels of “blocking patent” rights on each of the many patented components
 
which may be needed to produce a new commercial product.66 One way to avoid a
 
potential thicket is for competing patent holders to negotiate cross-licenses or “patent
 
pools.” Such agreements between competitors raise concerns about collusion, however,
 
and the societal ramifications depend upon the extent to which cross-licensing lowers
 
barriers to the use of complementary technologies (as opposed to allowing competitors to
 
avoid competition from substitute technologies).67
 
 
Patents and their citations form a directed network (meaning that citations go
 
from later patents to earlier patents and not in the opposite direction) in which patents are
 
the network “nodes” and citations are directed “links.” Citations convey valuable
 
information about the relationships between the technologies covered by the citing and
 
cited patents. The patent citation network thus can be viewed as a kind of map of the
 
space of patented technology, indicating the relationships between various pieces of
 
“property” in that space.77 As discussed in Part III.B, the evolution of the network may
 
help to illuminate whether patents are being awarded for more trivial technological steps.
 
While the precise significance of a patent citation varies, a citation sometimes
 
indicates that the claims of the cited patent encompass the claims of the citing patent and
 
that a “blocking patent” situation exists so that permission from both patent owners is
 
needed in order to use the invention claimed in the citing patent.
 
As will be discussed in
 
Part V, we believe it is likely that the structure of the patent citation “map” can be mined
 
for signatures of patent “thickets,” in which there is a high density of overlapping patent
 
claims, so as to test, for example, whether such “thickets” are increasingly prevalent in
 
the patent system.
 
 
A high density of patents in a particular technological “niche” need not always
 
indicate a patent thicket, however. Closely related patented technologies may be
 
potential substitutes for one another -- creating something more like patent supermarkets
 
offering many nearly interchangeable options than patent thickets. If these patents are
 
separately owned, competition between patent holders will reduce licensing fees and the
 
issue of hold-up will not arise.
 
 
Setting aside some technical issues about how to
 
compare citation densities from different sized network samples, citation density is a
 
useful way to assess the level of technological interrelatedness in a particular field.124
 
Density alone cannot distinguish between patent thickets and patent supermarkets, in
 
which closely related technologies compete for licensing “customers,” however. The
 
mere existence of a citation from one patent to another cannot tell us which scenario is
 
most likely. Determining the meaning of a particular citation is an extremely laborintensive
 
process requiring understanding of the legal and technical relationship between
 
the citing and cited patents. To investigate the existence of patent thickets and the
 
potential for related antitrust problems, some structural metric that is sensitive to the
 
character of a citation is highly desirable. It may be possible to design such a metric
 
based on transitivity concepts.
 
 
@article{taylor2003american,
 
  title={American Patent Policy, Biotechnology, and African Agriculture: The Case for Policy Change},
 
  author={Taylor, M.R. and Cayford, J.},
 
  journal={Harv. JL \& Tech.},
 
  volume={17},
 
  pages={321},
 
  year={2003},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Taylor Cayford (2003) - American Patent Policy Biotechnology And African Agriculture.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Effect of thickets on biotech for developing nations
 
 
According to one commentator writing about biotechnology
 
patents in the pharmaceutical field, “[w]ith cumulative
 
innovation and multiple blocking patents, stronger patent rights can
 
have the perverse effect of stifling, not encouraging, innovation.”71
 
 
(“PTO”) have created what some call a “patent
 
thicket” around biotechnology and how the PTO’s pro-patent culture
 
affects the proliferation of patents. We then identify policies affecting
 
access to patented technology and U.S. foreign policy on patents,
 
which may have more long-term impact on access to biotechnology in
 
developing countries than the PTO’s domestic patenting practices
 
 
 
@article{tullis2005application,
 
  title={Application of the Government License Defense to Federally Funded Nanotechnology Research: The Case for a Limited Patent Compulsory Licensing Regime},
 
  author={Tullis, T.K.},
 
  journal={UCLA L. Rev.},
 
  volume={53},
 
  pages={279},
 
  year={2005},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Tullis (2005) - Application Of The Government License Defense To Federally Funded Nanotechnology Research.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Policy Discussion: Solve thicket in nanotech using the Gov. License Defence.
 
 
GOVERNMENT LICENSE DEFENSE
 
IN FEDERALLY FUNDED NANOTECHNOLOGY RESEARCH
 
 
Unfortunately, the rush to secure worldwide intellectual property
 
rights in nanotechnology could lead to the development of a "patent
 
thicket." This term, coined by intellectual property scholars, refers to an
 
overlapping set of patent rights that requires researchers, inventors, and
 
entrepreneurs seeking to commercialize new technologies to obtain licenses
 
from multiple patentees. 5 The development of such a patent thicket could
 
deter further innovation, 6 and the active enforcement by nanotechnology
 
patent holders of their exclusivity rights ultimately could result in the creation
 
of a nanotechnology anticommons-a situation in which a scarce
 
resource becomes prone to underuse because there are too many owners
 
holding the right to exclude others from that resource, and no one has an
 
effective privilege of use.'
 
 
@article{turner2011patent,
 
  title={Patent Thickets, Trolls and Unproductive Entrepreneurship},
 
  author={Turner, J.},
 
  journal={Trolls and Unproductive Entrepreneurship (October 1, 2011)},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={Turner (2011) - Patent Thickets Trolls And Unproductive Entrepreneurship.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: Theory: Model of endogeneous thickets with trolls
 
 
I introduce and analyze an equilibrium model of invention, patenting and infringement under
 
monopolistic competition. Profitable use of inventions requires adaptation to complementary
 
technologies. With patents, a thicket of conflicting rights emerges and costly infringements
 
occur. This taxes invention and lowers welfare. When an inventor may be a “troll”—patent
 
without inventing—the rate of invention falls further. Intuitively, some trolls would invent if
 
it were impossible to be a troll. More technology is patented with trolls, so the thicket grows
 
and welfare falls. Being a troll is unprofitable unless a critical mass of inventions, made by
 
other firms, exists.
 
 
Patents grant their owners (“patentees”) the right to exclude others from using their
 
inventions. When multiple patents cover complementary components of a given technology,
 
a common contemporary phenomenon (Heller and Eisenberg 1998), multiple owners can
 
exclude each other from using the technology. Hence, producers often must navigate a
 
“thicket” of conflicting rights just to use their own inventions
 
 
My monopolistic competition model lets firms’ decisions of whether to invest in new
 
input technology and whether to patent both determine and depend on the endogenous rate
 
of invention and patenting in the economy. This enables study of how the complementarity
 
of technology affects incentives to invent both directly and through influencing the rate of
 
patenting. I show that an increase in input complementarity lowers equilibrium invention,
 
and typically raises the rate of patenting, by both increasing dispute costs paid and by
 
increasing the payoff to would-be patentees. This predicts that troll behavior should be
 
most harmful in industries where input complementarities are greatest.
 
 
@article{ukipo2011patentthickets,
 
  title={Patent Thickets: An overview},
 
  author={Intellectual Property Office Patent Informatics Team},
 
  journal={UK Intellectual Property Office},
 
  year={2011},
 
  filename={UKIPO (2011) - Patent Thickets An Overview.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Policy Report: CORE PAPER - Includes lit, terms and industry analysis and more
 
 
The phrase “patent thicket” is a descriptive term which highlights issues that new entrants to a market may face when attempting to innovate within, or enter into, a technology space having existing intellectual property rights. The most generally used definition of a thicket is that coined by Shapiro:
 
“a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology”
 
Equal weighting is given to fragmented technological areas (areas where there are large numbers of small patent holdings), or areas where there are small numbers of large players with large patent holdings, each of which creates a thicket that any entrants into the area will have to negotiate in order to be able to operate.
 
There is no clear consensus on terms used to describe patent thickets and the entities involved with them. If these terms were applied consistently, further debate on any issues could be conducted on a level playing field. Any change in policy associated with patent thickets should be carefully considered for its potential impact across different technology landscapes.
 
 
@article{vanoverwalle2010turning,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Turning Patent Swords into Shares},
 
  author = {Van Overwalle, Geertrui},
 
  journal = {Science},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {330},
 
  number = {6011},
 
  series = {New Series},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {17 December 2010},
 
  pages = {pp. 1630-1631},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/40964338},
 
  ISSN = {00368075},
 
  abstract = {},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2010},
 
  publisher = {American Association for the Advancement of Science},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2010 American Association for the Advancement of Science},
 
  filename={VanOverwalle (2010) - Turning Patent Swords Into Shares.pdf}
 
}
 
 
SciencePolicy: genes and thickets 2pgs.
 
 
Problems arise when “patent thickets” (a web
 
of overlapping patents through which a company
 
must “hack” in order to commercialize
 
a technology) emerge ( 12). Accumulation, or
 
“stacking,” of royalties that have to be paid
 
when confronted with a patent thicket may
 
lead to a “tragedy of the anti-commons” ( 13),
 
 
 
@article{van2006clearing,
 
  title={A clearing house for diagnostic testing: the solution to ensure access to and use of patented genetic inventions?},
 
  author={Van Zimmeren, E. and Verbeure, B. and Matthijs, G. and Van Overwalle, G.},
 
  journal={Bulletin of the World Health Organization},
 
  volume={84},
 
  number={5},
 
  pages={352--359},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={SciELO Public Health},
 
  filename={VanZimmeren (2006) - A Clearing House For Diagnostic Testing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
WHO Bulletin: 8 pages. Advocates clearing houses
 
 
Abstract In genetic diagnostics, the emergence of a so-called “patent thicket” is imminent. Such an overlapping set of patent
 
rights may have restrictive effects on further research and development of diagnostic tests, and the provision of clinical diagnostic
 
services. Currently, two models that may facilitate access to and use of patented genetic inventions are attracting much debate in
 
various national and international fora: patent pools and clearing houses. In this article, we explore the concept of clearing houses.
 
 
@article{verbeure2006patent,
 
  title={Patent pools and diagnostic testing},
 
  author={Verbeure, B. and van Zimmeren, E. and Matthijs, G. and Van Overwalle, G.},
 
  journal={TRENDS in Biotechnology},
 
  volume={24},
 
  number={3},
 
  pages={115--120},
 
  year={2006},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={Verbeure (2006) - Patent Pools And Diagnostic Testing.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Biology: 6pgs. Advocates Pools for diagnostic testing
 
 
There is increasing concern that overlapping patents in
 
the field of genetics will create a costly and legally
 
complex situation known as a patent thicket, which,
 
along with the associated issues of accumulating
 
royalty payments, can act as a disincentive for
 
innovation.
 
 
@article{von2011measure,
 
  title={How to measure patent thickets -- A novel approach},
 
  author={Von Graevenitz, G. and Wagner, S. and Harhoff, D.},
 
  journal={Economics Letters},
 
  volume={111},
 
  number={1},
 
  pages={6--9},
 
  year={2011},
 
  publisher={Elsevier},
 
  filename={VonGraevenitz Wagner Harhoff (2011) - How To Measure Patent Thickets  A Novel Approach.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: CORE PAPER!
 
 
2007). These patent explosions have had particularly
 
strong impact on technologies characterized by modular design and
 
high complexity of products such as electronics and semiconductors.
 
The combination of complex technology and high volume patenting
 
creates patent thickets, which can be defined as dense webs of
 
overlapping patent rights (Shapiro, 2001).
 
 
@article{von2012incidence,
 
  title={Incidence and Growth of Patent Thickets-The Impact of Technological Opportunities and Complexity},
 
  author={von Graevenitz, G. and Wagner, S. and Harhoff, D.},
 
  journal={Journal of Industrial Economics},
 
  year={2012},
 
  filename={vonGraevenitz (2012) - Incidence And Growth Of Patent Thickets.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: CORE PAPER
 
 
fragmentation index has predominantly been studied in complex industries (Ziedonis, 2004,
 
Schankerman and Noel, 2006) where increasing fragmentation raises firms’ patent applications.
 
This is attributed to firms’ efforts to reduce potential hold-up by opportunistic patentees
 
owning critical or blocking patent rights – a situation which is associated with the existence of
 
patent thickets. This index does not measure hold-up potential as precisely as the complexity
 
measure we discuss above.
 
The complexity measure combines information on actual blocking relationships within
 
technological opportunities which the fragmentation index does not.
 
 
@article{wagner2003information,
 
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
 
  title = {Information Wants to Be Free: Intellectual Property and the Mythologies of Control},
 
  author = {Wagner, R. Polk},
 
  journal = {Columbia Law Review},
 
  jstor_issuetitle = {},
 
  volume = {103},
 
  number = {4},
 
  jstor_formatteddate = {May, 2003},
 
  pages = {pp. 995-1034},
 
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/1123783},
 
  ISSN = {00101958},
 
  abstract = {This Essay challenges a central tenet of the recent criticism of intellectual property rights: the suggestion that the control conferred by such rights is detrimental to the continued flourishing of a public domain of ideas and information. In this Essay, Professor Wagner argues that such theories understate the significance of the intangible nature of information, and thus overlook the contribution that even perfectly controlled intellectual creations make to the public domain. In addition, this Essay shows that perfect control of propertized information--an animating assumption in much of the contemporary criticism--is both counterfactual and likely to remain so. These findings suggest that increasing the appropriability of information goods is likely to increase, rather than diminish, the quantity of "open" information. Further, the benefits of control in fostering coordination and enabling flexibility in arrangements are essential elements of promoting progress in a changing world.},
 
  language = {English},
 
  year = {2003},
 
  publisher = {Columbia Law Review Association, Inc.},
 
  copyright = {Copyright © 2003 Columbia Law Review Association, Inc.},
 
  filename={Wagner (2003) - Information Wants To Be Free.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Theory/Discussion: Don't worry about the 'control' aspect, information will be free anyway
 
 
Contemporary criticism of intellectual property rights is notable for
 
its clear focus on the control inherent in the system of government-extended
 
grants of exclusivity-in particular the assertion that such control
 
is in tension with the development of a public domain of information.2
 
This development is (and has been) both intellectually and rhetorically
 
significant. Intellectually, by emphasizing the effects of control, these
 
critics can support intellectual property generally, yet condemn it specifically,
 
where the pernicious side effects of the mechanism are seen. In a
 
way, this approach seems to have largely transcended the more abstract
 
question of whether intellectual property is a socially useful tool, and focused
 
our attention on the specifics.3 Rhetorically, an entire vocabulary
 
has been built to support this line of argument. Control-talk is of "the
 
second enclosure movement,"4 the lurking "tragedy of the anticom-
 
mons,"5 or the dangers of "patent thickets"6 -not to mention the phenomenon
 
of litigation efforts (or perhaps social movements?) sporting
 
their own slogans (and logos), such as "Free the Mouse," "Create Like It's
 
1790," or "When Copyright Attacks."7
 
 
This Essay challenges a major tenet of this control-criticism: the
 
claim that control will reduce the availability of information in the public
 
domain.8 The core contention here is that the critics understate-perhaps
 
dramatically-the contribution that even "perfect" control of intellectual
 
creations makes to the public domain, just as they overstate the
 
current and potential effectiveness of this control. Combining this understanding
 
with the dynamic incentive-effects of intellectual property
 
rights suggests that such rights (even in strong forms) are likely to increase
 
the content of the public domain rather than decrease it. Thus,
 
while there are perhaps other reasons to limit the scope and enforceability
 
of intellectual property rights, concern about the withering of the public
 
domain seems not to be one of them.
 
 
Notwithstanding
 
efforts to the contrary, information cannot truly be controlled, at least
 
not in the way that the control-critics suggest. That is, the "fencing" of
 
information is a remarkably futile proposition; the control we offer owners
 
of intellectual property rights is simply not the control we offer landowners.
 
It should not be, but more importantly, it cannot be. It turns out
 
that information does "want to be free."' 4 Understanding that this is the
 
great strength of intellectual property, as well as the great challenge, offers
 
a new perspective on the function of control and the benefits of
 
strong intellectual property rights.'5
 
 
 
@article{wang2010rise,
 
  title={Rise of the patent intermediaries},
 
  author={Wang, A.W.},
 
  journal={Berkeley Tech. LJ},
 
  volume={25},
 
  pages={159},
 
  year={2010},
 
  publisher={HeinOnline},
 
  filename={Wang (2010) - Rise Of The Patent Intermediaries.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Law: Intermediaries as a solution to thickets
 
 
In this age
 
of patent thickets,60 an organization must tread carefully lest it infringe
 
countless patents just by doing business,61 and an aggregate license to a large
 
cluster of patents in the appropriate field of technology can provide peace
 
of mind. Moreover, an aggregate license lowers the search costs for a
 
member company planning to embark on a plan of research and
 
development in a particular field. Defensive aggregation services strive for
 
complete adoption by all players in the market and the resulting obsolescence
 
of expenditures on patent searches and license negotiations. Though this
 
scenario may never actually come to pass, companies are likely to have great
 
interest in partnering with an entity able to bring them closer to this ideal.
 
 
@article{ziedonis2004don,
 
  title={Don't fence me in: Fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms},
 
  author={Ziedonis, R.H.},
 
  journal={Management Science},
 
  volume={50},
 
  number={6},
 
  pages={804--820},
 
  year={2004},
 
  publisher={INFORMS},
 
  filename={Ziedonis (2004) - Dont Fence Me In.pdf}
 
}
 
 
Econ: CORE PAPER!!!
 

Latest revision as of 00:27, 26 March 2013

This page is part of the Patent Thicket Litature Review

Notes

This page contains the Annotated BibTeX Master file. It is a series of BibTeX entries, sorted approximately alphabetically by author, with notes after each entry. The notes were written during the second step of the review process and should not be trusted. Notes should only be erased when entries leave this file. At present entries should only leave this file when they have been edited and updated with the appropriate tags and entered into the PTLR Up Group Processed BibTeX. If/when this file is copied to a text file for remote work, please keep this header.

The Master File

@article{gugler2007market,
  jstor_articletype = {research-article},
  title = {Market Power versus Efficiency Effects of Mergers and Research Joint Ventures: Evidence from the Semiconductor Industry},
  author = {Gugler, Klaus and Siebert, Ralph},
  journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
  volume = {89},
  number = {4},
  jstor_formatteddate = {Nov., 2007},
  pages = {pp. 645-659},
  url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/40043091},
  ISSN = {00346535},
  abstract = {Merger control authorities may approve a merger based on an "efficiency defense." An important aspect in clearing mergers is that the efficiencies need to be merger-specific. Joint ventures, and in particular research joint ventures (RJVs), may achieve comparable efficiencies possibly without the anticompetitive (market power) effects of mergers. We empirically account for the endogenous formation of mergers and RJVs and provide evidence that at the semiconductor level, mergers and RJVs achieve dominant (net) efficiency effects. Our counterfactuals provide evidence that the efficiency gains caused by mergers would have been achieved by RJVs as well. Therefore, RJVs often represent viable alternatives to mergers from the consumer welfare point of view. At the more disaggregate level we find that the efficiency effects are larger in the microcomponents than in the memory market. This finding emphasizes the importance of market determinants (such as product differentiation and entry) having an impact on efficiency and market power effects.},
  language = {English},
  year = {2007},
  publisher = {The MIT Press},
  copyright = {Copyright © 2007 The MIT Press},
  filename={Gugler Siebert (2007) - Market Power Versus Efficiency Effects Of Mergers And Research Joint Ventures.pdf}
}

Econ: Semiconductor: Efficiency of mergers

Our counterfactuals pro- vide evidence that the efficiency gains caused by mergers would have been achieved by RJVs as well. Therefore, RJVs often represent viable alternatives to mergers from the consumer welfare point of view. At the more disaggregate level we find that the efficiency effects are larger in the microcomponents than in the memory market. This finding emphasizes the importance of market determinants (such as product differentiation and entry) having an impact on efficiency and market power effects

Incre- mental process innovations occur more frequently in the memory segment, creating a higher density of the patent thicket. This fact is in line with the patent thicket literature see, for example, Hall and Ziedonis (2001) and Shapiro (2001).1

@techreport{lerner2003cooperative,
  title={Cooperative marketing agreements between competitors: evidence from patent pools},
  author={Lerner, J. and Tirole, J. and Strojwas, M.},
  year={2003},
  institution={National Bureau of Economic Research},
  filename={Lerner Tirole Strojwas (2003) - Cooperative Marketing Agreements Between Competitors.pdf}
}

DISCARD: Appears to be almost identical to: Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2003) - The Structure And Performance Of Patent Pools Empirical Evidence