Difference between revisions of "Geradin (2007) - Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality"

From edegan.com
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>John
 
(6 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 +
{{Article
 +
|Has page=Geradin (2007) - Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality
 +
|Has bibtex key=
 +
|Has article title=Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality
 +
|Has author=Geradin
 +
|Has year=2007
 +
|In journal=
 +
|In volume=
 +
|In number=
 +
|Has pages=
 +
|Has publisher=
 +
}}
 
*This page is referenced in the [[Patent Thicket Literature Review]]
 
*This page is referenced in the [[Patent Thicket Literature Review]]
 
*This page is listed on the [[PTLR Core Papers]] page
 
*This page is listed on the [[PTLR Core Papers]] page
Line 33: Line 45:
 
==Review==
 
==Review==
  
===Definition of patent thicket===
+
===Theoretical Model===
:''"And thus so have fears of “royalty stacking”, whereby the number of licenses required to bring a product or service to the marketplace stack up, one atop the other, potentially creating an insurmountable barrier to commercialization."''
+
TBD
  
===Legal Discussion===
+
===Measures of Patent Thicket===
 +
Quantitative measures of patent thicket or royalty stacking effects is:
 +
*Citation concentration of the top 4 firms in a technology area:
 +
**The measure sums citation shares of each of the top 4 firm's backward patent citations to the other firm's patents at a point in time;
 +
**As a robustness check, the authors also considered an 8 firm concentration measure and a traditional HHI measures based on sum of squared citations, and obtained qualitatively similar effects.
  
*Literature review and policy discussion of high-tech industries.
+
===Sample===
 +
The data analyzes 63 firms with at least one 3G patent over the period from 1996-2005:
 +
*The universe of 60 firms contributing patents to the 3G telecomm standard, plus 82 firms in SIC code 3663 (Radio and Television Broadcasting and Communications Equipment) and 4812 (Radiophone and Communications) was restricted to those with at least one U.S. 3G patent.
 +
*Firm financial data (sales, assets, employees) for 1980-2005 is drawn from Compustat.
 +
*Patent data (grant dates, technology classes, citations and prior art listing) from USPTO.
  
*Patent protection is an important incentive for innovation.
+
===Results===
:''"The first innovators need sufficiently strong rights to create sufficient incentives to induce their pioneering work, but enough profit potential needs to remain for second innovators so that they will invest if it is efficient for them to do so."''
+
:''"Since concentration at this level has nearly no statistically significant effect on firm market value, we conclude that four firms translate into concentration for this industry and fragmentation is low among public cellular telecom firms, especially among vertically integrated firms. Thus, we find that the predicted royalty stacking problem is not an issue in this industry."''
 
+
*R&D spillover effects are positively related to market value for upstream firms, but negatively related for vertically integrated and Operator firms, although estimates are not significant;
*In high-tech industries, it has been claimed that cumulative innovation and dispersed patent ownership create an environment where licenses are too expensive.
+
*Patenting propensity is negatively related to market value for upstream and vertically integrated firms, but positivey among Operator firms, and estimates are significant for vertically integrated firms.
:''"…market-driven mechanisms, such as cross licensing, patent pools, and reputation effects, are considered insufficient to completely solve royalty stacking, especially in industries such as telecommunications and computing where new technologies frequently develop under the auspices of standard setting organizations."''
+
*The patent thicket measure, citation concentation, is positively related to market value for upstream and vertically integrated firms, negative for operators, although estimates are not significant.
 
+
*Insignificant results may reflect the low levels of fragmentation in this data - the concentration measure for public cellular telecom firms ranges from 53% to 100% with an average of 83%, indicating that most patent citations are concentrated in the top 4 firms.
*Author finds little evidence that royalty stacking under current law is not solved by cross licensing, patent pools, repeat play reputation, or other mechanisms.
 
**While one may argue that evidence of royalty stacking is difficult to find because, if a market collapses, products and services are not produced to determine royalty rates, signs should be observed well before a market collapse occurs.
 
  
 
===Social Welfare Consequences===
 
===Social Welfare Consequences===
*Examples of patent holdup are rare and often involve short term players in the market, which calls for caution in broader reforms of the patent system.
+
:''"The royalty stacking theory is not robust and, what is most important, even in such industries where innovation is cumulative and products integrate many components each of which may be subject to one or more patents, there is no real evidence that royalty stacking is a problem in practice. In contrast to recent claims by Lemley and Shapiro (2006), we find no evidence of a significant royalty stacking problem in the 3G telecoms industry...The empirical and theoretical results of this Essay seriously question the underpinnings of recent proposals advocating various changes in antitrust enforcement and patent law, which are meant to address the purported tragedy of the anti-commons and the misfortunes caused by ever growing patent thickets."''
:''"Solid patent reforms are probably among the best ways to alleviate the risk of royalty stacking and other licensing issues, as stemming the patent flood and eliminating weak patents would reduce overall patent counts and limit those remaining to valuable contributions. As with all reforms, patent reform should be done with care to avoid unintended consequences."''
 
  
===Policy Advocated in Paper===
+
===Dependent Variable and Model===
*It is widely recognized that IPR reform is needed.
+
The dependent variable is Tobin's Q (ratio of firm's market value to tangible assets).
**While anecdotal evidence shows that problems exists in the patent system, the issues are not regular enough to justify any currently proposed policy change as the costs will outweigh the benefits.
+
*The model specification is OLS with robust standard errors.
**Any reforms should complement existing voluntary market mechanisms.
+
*Patenting control variables include:
:''"In the end, considering both the scant evidence that royalty stacking and other complements issues are widespread and recurring problems, along with the availability of several countervailing market responses, we find that were society to implement several of these policy recommendations it would risk setting a course for Scylla in the absence of any evidence of danger from Charybdis."''
+
**Citation Concentration, meant to capture patent thickets or royalty stacking effects (see above for definition);
 +
**Patenting propensity, as measured by the firm's patent stock and R&D stock in a given year;
 +
**Spillover, as measured by the sum of R&D spending of close competitors weighted by the citation concentation, which is the uncentered correlation between the two firms patent citations (excluding self-citations) across technology classes.
 +
**Each of these patenting variables is interacted with indicators of whether the firm has an Operator or an upstream/vertically integrated structure.
 +
*Firm and industry controls are:
 +
**Shadow cost of physical capital, measured by ratio off R&D spending to tangible assets (net stock of property, plant and equipment), and higher order terms;
 +
**Shadow cost of intellectual capital, measured by ratio of the number of a firm's patents to tangible assets (net stock of property, plant and equipment), and higher order terms;
 +
**Indicators of whether firms are Operators, Upstream (design firms such as Qualcomm) or Vertically Integrated firms (>10% of revenue from manufacturing), with vertically integrated firms as the omitted group;
 +
**log Net sales and its lag;
 +
**Technological opportunity in a technology area, as measured by the logarithm of the weighted sum of the patent stock of a company's technologically close competitors for each patent technology class, and a lag;
 +
**Year and industry indicators.

Latest revision as of 19:14, 29 September 2020

Article
Has bibtex key
Has article title Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality
Has author Geradin
Has year 2007
In journal
In volume
In number
Has pages
Has publisher
© edegan.com, 2016

Reference

  • Geradin, D., Layne-Farrar, A. and Padilla Blanco, A. (2007), "Royalty stacking in high tech industries: separating myth from reality", Working Paper
@article{geradin2007royalty,
  title={Royalty stacking in high tech industries: separating myth from reality},
  author={Geradin, D. and Layne-Farrar, A. and Padilla Blanco, A.},
  year={2007},
  abstract={A few recent contributions to the literature have claimed that in high-tech industries -- where innovation is often cumulative and products include many components protected by patents held by many different patent holders – the cost of obtaining all necessary licenses is too high. Some have even requested sweeping policy reforms to deal with the so-called royalty stacking problem. In this Essay we find that the empirical evidence – including new evidence for 3G telecom – does not corroborate the gloomy predictions of the proponents of the royalty stacking hypothesis. A careful look at the theoretical underpinnings of this hypothesis explains the lack of empirical support. First, three necessary conditions must be satisfied for a royalty stacking problem to exist: (a) innovation must be cumulative, so that the patents are complementary; (b) there must be many patents for a given product; and (c) the many patents must be held by numerous, distinct rights holders. Buy royalty stacking may not be a problem even if the three necessary conditions are met; i.e., the three conditions are necessary but not sufficient. Moreover, several market mechanisms, such as cross licensing or voluntary patent pools, can be used to mitigate the costs of multiple concurrent patent negotiations. We conclude that the so-called royalty stacking problem is more myth than reality and that there is no reason to adopt the dramatic reforms in antitrust and patent law that have been recently proposed.},
  discipline={Econ},
  research_type={Empirical},
  industry={},
  thicket_stance={},
  thicket_stance_extract={},
  thicket_def={},
  thicket_def_extract={},  
  tags={},
  filename={Geradin (2007) - Royalty Stacking In High Tech Industries Separating Myth From Reality.pdf}
}

File(s)

Abstract

A few recent contributions to the literature have claimed that in high-tech industries -- where innovation is often cumulative and products include many components protected by patents held by many different patent holders – the cost of obtaining all necessary licenses is too high. Some have even requested sweeping policy reforms to deal with the so-called royalty stacking problem. In this Essay we find that the empirical evidence – including new evidence for 3G telecom – does not corroborate the gloomy predictions of the proponents of the royalty stacking hypothesis. A careful look at the theoretical underpinnings of this hypothesis explains the lack of empirical support. First, three necessary conditions must be satisfied for a royalty stacking problem to exist: (a) innovation must be cumulative, so that the patents are complementary; (b) there must be many patents for a given product; and (c) the many patents must be held by numerous, distinct rights holders. Buy royalty stacking may not be a problem even if the three necessary conditions are met; i.e., the three conditions are necessary but not sufficient. Moreover, several market mechanisms, such as cross licensing or voluntary patent pools, can be used to mitigate the costs of multiple concurrent patent negotiations. We conclude that the so-called royalty stacking problem is more myth than reality and that there is no reason to adopt the dramatic reforms in antitrust and patent law that have been recently proposed.

Review

Theoretical Model

TBD

Measures of Patent Thicket

Quantitative measures of patent thicket or royalty stacking effects is:

  • Citation concentration of the top 4 firms in a technology area:
    • The measure sums citation shares of each of the top 4 firm's backward patent citations to the other firm's patents at a point in time;
    • As a robustness check, the authors also considered an 8 firm concentration measure and a traditional HHI measures based on sum of squared citations, and obtained qualitatively similar effects.

Sample

The data analyzes 63 firms with at least one 3G patent over the period from 1996-2005:

  • The universe of 60 firms contributing patents to the 3G telecomm standard, plus 82 firms in SIC code 3663 (Radio and Television Broadcasting and Communications Equipment) and 4812 (Radiophone and Communications) was restricted to those with at least one U.S. 3G patent.
  • Firm financial data (sales, assets, employees) for 1980-2005 is drawn from Compustat.
  • Patent data (grant dates, technology classes, citations and prior art listing) from USPTO.

Results

"Since concentration at this level has nearly no statistically significant effect on firm market value, we conclude that four firms translate into concentration for this industry and fragmentation is low among public cellular telecom firms, especially among vertically integrated firms. Thus, we find that the predicted royalty stacking problem is not an issue in this industry."
  • R&D spillover effects are positively related to market value for upstream firms, but negatively related for vertically integrated and Operator firms, although estimates are not significant;
  • Patenting propensity is negatively related to market value for upstream and vertically integrated firms, but positivey among Operator firms, and estimates are significant for vertically integrated firms.
  • The patent thicket measure, citation concentation, is positively related to market value for upstream and vertically integrated firms, negative for operators, although estimates are not significant.
  • Insignificant results may reflect the low levels of fragmentation in this data - the concentration measure for public cellular telecom firms ranges from 53% to 100% with an average of 83%, indicating that most patent citations are concentrated in the top 4 firms.

Social Welfare Consequences

"The royalty stacking theory is not robust and, what is most important, even in such industries where innovation is cumulative and products integrate many components each of which may be subject to one or more patents, there is no real evidence that royalty stacking is a problem in practice. In contrast to recent claims by Lemley and Shapiro (2006), we find no evidence of a significant royalty stacking problem in the 3G telecoms industry...The empirical and theoretical results of this Essay seriously question the underpinnings of recent proposals advocating various changes in antitrust enforcement and patent law, which are meant to address the purported tragedy of the anti-commons and the misfortunes caused by ever growing patent thickets."

Dependent Variable and Model

The dependent variable is Tobin's Q (ratio of firm's market value to tangible assets).

  • The model specification is OLS with robust standard errors.
  • Patenting control variables include:
    • Citation Concentration, meant to capture patent thickets or royalty stacking effects (see above for definition);
    • Patenting propensity, as measured by the firm's patent stock and R&D stock in a given year;
    • Spillover, as measured by the sum of R&D spending of close competitors weighted by the citation concentation, which is the uncentered correlation between the two firms patent citations (excluding self-citations) across technology classes.
    • Each of these patenting variables is interacted with indicators of whether the firm has an Operator or an upstream/vertically integrated structure.
  • Firm and industry controls are:
    • Shadow cost of physical capital, measured by ratio off R&D spending to tangible assets (net stock of property, plant and equipment), and higher order terms;
    • Shadow cost of intellectual capital, measured by ratio of the number of a firm's patents to tangible assets (net stock of property, plant and equipment), and higher order terms;
    • Indicators of whether firms are Operators, Upstream (design firms such as Qualcomm) or Vertically Integrated firms (>10% of revenue from manufacturing), with vertically integrated firms as the omitted group;
    • log Net sales and its lag;
    • Technological opportunity in a technology area, as measured by the logarithm of the weighted sum of the patent stock of a company's technologically close competitors for each patent technology class, and a lag;
    • Year and industry indicators.