Changes

Jump to navigation Jump to search
no edit summary
==Reference(s)==
Williamson, Oliver E. (1971), "The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations," American Economic Review, 61:112-23. [http://www.edegan.com/pdfs/Williamson%20(1971)%20-%20The%20Vertical%20Integration%20of%20Production.pdf pdf]
 
==Abstract==
The study of vertical integration has presented difficulties at both theoretical and policy levels of analysis. That vertical integration has never enjoyed a secure place in value theory is attributable to the fact that, under conventional assumptions, it is an anomaly: if the costs of operating competitive markets are zero, "as is usually assumed in our theoretical analysis" (Arrow, 1969, p. 48), why integrate?
 
 
==Background==
 
The context of the paper is as follows:
*Firms have a coordinating advantage over markets
**Markets have "Transactional Failure"
*'''Transaction costs''' are important '''only where adaptation is needed'''.
**Adaptation is making a '''relational specific investment'''
*The focus on the paper is on '''incentives''' (opportunistic behaviour is following one's incentives, rationally) and '''control''' in the firm vs in the market.
*The paper considers only when firms are better, not what makes them worse
*The properties of governance are: '''incentives''', '''control''', and "inherent structural advantages" (though it isn't clear what the last term means).
**Control is '''fiat''', which is more efficient than haggling or litigation.
*A Firm <math>\equiv</math> "Long term sequential contracts with a fixed arbitrator"
 
==The Theory==
 
===The Methodology===
 
The methodology is to apply the '''Discriminating Alignment Hypothesis'''.
 
That is to find what causes problems and then argue how a specific organizational form solves (i.e. has structural advantages).
 
===Ingredient I===
 
Suppose there are a few suppliers for a component that fits into a larger product
 
'''Argument I''': Bilateral monopoly is not itself a big problem (without double marginalization):
*There will be bargaining over the surplus - and haggling is costly, which reduces resources (c.f. [http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Coase%27s_theorem Coase's theorem] and Tullock - Rent dissapation in a contest), at least in the presence of transaction costs.
*If there is haggling then vertical integration (VI) solves the problem
*So do spot contracts (either over the contract or other the integration)
**Therefore VI is as good as a contract (and is a contract!).
 
===Ingredient II===
 
Suppose there are incomplete contracts, but that otherwise we are in a world of Arrow-Debreu securities.
 
There are three potential solutions:
#A long term contract
#A sequence of short term contracts
#Vertical Integration
 
For long term contracts to work they need to be Arrow-Debreu contigent contracts.
*Writing a contract for every state of the world is costly - assume prohibitively, as otherwise there is no need for the contract to be incomplete
 
There must be '''adaption''' on the equilibrium path, which implies the possibility of strategic (opportunistic) behaviour.
 
Can short term contracts solve this problem?
*Not if there are '''relational specific investments''' (c.f. Klien, Crawford and Alchian, or Grossman and Hart)
*Not is there are '''ex-post relational specific advantages''' (c.f. Masten and Synder)
 
The main tradeoff is between: '''Optimal investment''' and '''Optimal sequential adaptation'''. These are at odds. VI solves this tradeoff!
Anonymous user

Navigation menu